CA2556957A1 - Enhanced parimutuel wagering - Google Patents

Enhanced parimutuel wagering Download PDF

Info

Publication number
CA2556957A1
CA2556957A1 CA002556957A CA2556957A CA2556957A1 CA 2556957 A1 CA2556957 A1 CA 2556957A1 CA 002556957 A CA002556957 A CA 002556957A CA 2556957 A CA2556957 A CA 2556957A CA 2556957 A1 CA2556957 A1 CA 2556957A1
Authority
CA
Canada
Prior art keywords
fundamental
bet
outcome
wager
odds
Prior art date
Legal status (The legal status is an assumption and is not a legal conclusion. Google has not performed a legal analysis and makes no representation as to the accuracy of the status listed.)
Abandoned
Application number
CA002556957A
Other languages
French (fr)
Inventor
Jeffrey Lange
Kenneth Charles Baron
Charles Walden
Marcus Harte
Current Assignee (The listed assignees may be inaccurate. Google has not performed a legal analysis and makes no representation or warranty as to the accuracy of the list.)
Longitude Inc
Original Assignee
Longitude, Inc.
Jeffrey Lange
Kenneth Charles Baron
Charles Walden
Marcus Harte
Priority date (The priority date is an assumption and is not a legal conclusion. Google has not performed a legal analysis and makes no representation as to the accuracy of the date listed.)
Filing date
Publication date
Application filed by Longitude, Inc., Jeffrey Lange, Kenneth Charles Baron, Charles Walden, Marcus Harte filed Critical Longitude, Inc.
Publication of CA2556957A1 publication Critical patent/CA2556957A1/en
Abandoned legal-status Critical Current

Links

Classifications

    • GPHYSICS
    • G06COMPUTING; CALCULATING OR COUNTING
    • G06QINFORMATION AND COMMUNICATION TECHNOLOGY [ICT] SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES; SYSTEMS OR METHODS SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES, NOT OTHERWISE PROVIDED FOR
    • G06Q50/00Systems or methods specially adapted for specific business sectors, e.g. utilities or tourism
    • G06Q50/34Betting or bookmaking, e.g. Internet betting
    • GPHYSICS
    • G07CHECKING-DEVICES
    • G07FCOIN-FREED OR LIKE APPARATUS
    • G07F17/00Coin-freed apparatus for hiring articles; Coin-freed facilities or services
    • G07F17/32Coin-freed apparatus for hiring articles; Coin-freed facilities or services for games, toys, sports, or amusements
    • G07F17/3286Type of games
    • G07F17/3288Betting, e.g. on live events, bookmaking
    • GPHYSICS
    • G06COMPUTING; CALCULATING OR COUNTING
    • G06QINFORMATION AND COMMUNICATION TECHNOLOGY [ICT] SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES; SYSTEMS OR METHODS SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES, NOT OTHERWISE PROVIDED FOR
    • G06Q40/00Finance; Insurance; Tax strategies; Processing of corporate or income taxes
    • G06Q40/04Trading; Exchange, e.g. stocks, commodities, derivatives or currency exchange
    • GPHYSICS
    • G07CHECKING-DEVICES
    • G07FCOIN-FREED OR LIKE APPARATUS
    • G07F17/00Coin-freed apparatus for hiring articles; Coin-freed facilities or services
    • G07F17/32Coin-freed apparatus for hiring articles; Coin-freed facilities or services for games, toys, sports, or amusements
    • GPHYSICS
    • G07CHECKING-DEVICES
    • G07FCOIN-FREED OR LIKE APPARATUS
    • G07F17/00Coin-freed apparatus for hiring articles; Coin-freed facilities or services
    • G07F17/32Coin-freed apparatus for hiring articles; Coin-freed facilities or services for games, toys, sports, or amusements
    • G07F17/3286Type of games
    • G07F17/329Regular and instant lottery, e.g. electronic scratch cards
    • GPHYSICS
    • G07CHECKING-DEVICES
    • G07FCOIN-FREED OR LIKE APPARATUS
    • G07F7/00Mechanisms actuated by objects other than coins to free or to actuate vending, hiring, coin or paper currency dispensing or refunding apparatus
    • G07F7/08Mechanisms actuated by objects other than coins to free or to actuate vending, hiring, coin or paper currency dispensing or refunding apparatus by coded identity card or credit card or other personal identification means
    • G07F7/10Mechanisms actuated by objects other than coins to free or to actuate vending, hiring, coin or paper currency dispensing or refunding apparatus by coded identity card or credit card or other personal identification means together with a coded signal, e.g. in the form of personal identification information, like personal identification number [PIN] or biometric data
    • HELECTRICITY
    • H01ELECTRIC ELEMENTS
    • H01LSEMICONDUCTOR DEVICES NOT COVERED BY CLASS H10
    • H01L21/00Processes or apparatus adapted for the manufacture or treatment of semiconductor or solid state devices or of parts thereof
    • H01L21/02Manufacture or treatment of semiconductor devices or of parts thereof
    • H01L21/04Manufacture or treatment of semiconductor devices or of parts thereof the devices having at least one potential-jump barrier or surface barrier, e.g. PN junction, depletion layer or carrier concentration layer
    • H01L21/18Manufacture or treatment of semiconductor devices or of parts thereof the devices having at least one potential-jump barrier or surface barrier, e.g. PN junction, depletion layer or carrier concentration layer the devices having semiconductor bodies comprising elements of Group IV of the Periodic System or AIIIBV compounds with or without impurities, e.g. doping materials
    • H01L21/28Manufacture of electrodes on semiconductor bodies using processes or apparatus not provided for in groups H01L21/20 - H01L21/268
    • H01L21/28008Making conductor-insulator-semiconductor electrodes
    • H01L21/28017Making conductor-insulator-semiconductor electrodes the insulator being formed after the semiconductor body, the semiconductor being silicon
    • H01L21/28026Making conductor-insulator-semiconductor electrodes the insulator being formed after the semiconductor body, the semiconductor being silicon characterised by the conductor
    • H01L21/28035Making conductor-insulator-semiconductor electrodes the insulator being formed after the semiconductor body, the semiconductor being silicon characterised by the conductor the final conductor layer next to the insulator being silicon, e.g. polysilicon, with or without impurities
    • H01L21/28044Making conductor-insulator-semiconductor electrodes the insulator being formed after the semiconductor body, the semiconductor being silicon characterised by the conductor the final conductor layer next to the insulator being silicon, e.g. polysilicon, with or without impurities the conductor comprising at least another non-silicon conductive layer
    • H01L21/28061Making conductor-insulator-semiconductor electrodes the insulator being formed after the semiconductor body, the semiconductor being silicon characterised by the conductor the final conductor layer next to the insulator being silicon, e.g. polysilicon, with or without impurities the conductor comprising at least another non-silicon conductive layer the conductor comprising a metal or metal silicide formed by deposition, e.g. sputter deposition, i.e. without a silicidation reaction
    • HELECTRICITY
    • H01ELECTRIC ELEMENTS
    • H01LSEMICONDUCTOR DEVICES NOT COVERED BY CLASS H10
    • H01L29/00Semiconductor devices adapted for rectifying, amplifying, oscillating or switching, or capacitors or resistors with at least one potential-jump barrier or surface barrier, e.g. PN junction depletion layer or carrier concentration layer; Details of semiconductor bodies or of electrodes thereof  ; Multistep manufacturing processes therefor
    • H01L29/40Electrodes ; Multistep manufacturing processes therefor
    • H01L29/43Electrodes ; Multistep manufacturing processes therefor characterised by the materials of which they are formed
    • H01L29/49Metal-insulator-semiconductor electrodes, e.g. gates of MOSFET
    • H01L29/4916Metal-insulator-semiconductor electrodes, e.g. gates of MOSFET the conductor material next to the insulator being a silicon layer, e.g. polysilicon doped with boron, phosphorus or nitrogen
    • H01L29/4925Metal-insulator-semiconductor electrodes, e.g. gates of MOSFET the conductor material next to the insulator being a silicon layer, e.g. polysilicon doped with boron, phosphorus or nitrogen with a multiple layer structure, e.g. several silicon layers with different crystal structure or grain arrangement
    • H01L29/4941Metal-insulator-semiconductor electrodes, e.g. gates of MOSFET the conductor material next to the insulator being a silicon layer, e.g. polysilicon doped with boron, phosphorus or nitrogen with a multiple layer structure, e.g. several silicon layers with different crystal structure or grain arrangement with a barrier layer between the silicon and the metal or metal silicide upper layer, e.g. Silicide/TiN/Polysilicon

Abstract

Methods and systems for engaging in enhanced parimutuel wagering and gaming.
In one embodiment, different types of bets can be offered and processed in the same betting pool on an underlying event, such as a horse or dog race, a sporting event or a lottery, and the premiums and payouts of these different types of bets can be determined in the same betting pool, by configuring an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for each type of bet, and performing a demand-based valuation of each of the fundamental bets in the equivalent combination. In another embodiment, bettors can place bets in the betting pool with limit odds on the selected outcome of the underlying event.
The bets with limit odds are not filled in whole or in part, unless the final odds on the selected outcome of the underlying event are equal to or greater than the limit odds.

Description

DEMANDE OU BREVET VOLUMINEUX
LA PRESENTE PARTIE DE CETTE DEMANDE OU CE BREVET COMPREND
PLUS D'UN TOME.

NOTE : Pour les tomes additionels, veuillez contacter 1e Bureau canadien des brevets JUMBO APPLICATIONS/PATENTS
THIS SECTION OF THE APPLICATION/PATENT CONTAINS MORE THAN ONE
VOLUME

NOTE: For additional volumes, please contact the Canadian Patent Office NOM DU FICHIER / FILE NAME
NOTE POUR LE TOME / VOLUME NOTE:

ENHANCED PARIMUTUEL WAGERING
COPYRIGHT NOTICE
This document contains material that is subject to copyright protection. The applicant has no objection to the facsimile reproduction of this patent document, as it appears in the U.S.
Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) patent file or records or in any publication by the PTO or counterpart foreign or international instrumentalities. The applicant .otherwise reserves all copyright rights whatsoever.
RELATED APPLICATIONS
This application is a continuation-in-part of United States application serial number 10/365,033, filed February 11, 2003, which is a continuation-in-part of United States application serial number 10/115,505, filed April 2, 2002, which is a continuation-in-part ofUnited States application serial number 09/950,498, filed September 10, 2001, which is a continuation-in-part.
of United States application serial number 09/809,025, filed March 16, 2001, which is.a continuation-in-part of United States application serial number 09/774,816, initially filed January 30, 2001 and attributed a filing date of April 3, 2001 as the United States national stage application under 35 U.S.C. ~ 371 of Patent Cooperation Treaty application serial number PCT/C1S00/19447 (filed July 18, 2000), which is a continuation-in-part of United States application serial number 09/448,822, filed November 24, 1999. This application also claims priority to Patent Cooperation Treaty application serial number PCT/CTS00/19447, filed July 18, 2000; and United States provisional application serial number 60/144,890, filed July 21, 1999.
Each of the applications referred to in this paragraph is incorporated by reference in its entirety into this application.
FIELD OF THE INVENTION
This invention relates to systems and methods for enhanced parimutuel wagering and gaming. More specifically, this invention relates to methods and systems for enabling different types of bets to be offered in the same betting pool, and for determining the premiums and payouts of these different types of bets in the same betting pool, -by configuring an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for each type of bet, and performing a demand-based valuation of each of the fundamental bets in the equivalent combination. This invention also relates to methods and systems for enabling and determining values for bets placed in the betting pool with limit odds on the selected outcome of the underlying wagering event. The bets with limit odds are not filled in whole or in part, unless the final odds on the selected outcome of the underlying event are equal to or greater than the Limit odds.
BACKGROUND OF THE INVENTION
With the rapid increase in usage and popularity of the public Internet, the growth of electronic Internet-based trading of securities has been dramatic. In the first part of 1999, online trading via the Internet was estimated to make up approximately 15% of all stock trades. This volume has been growing at an annual rate of~proximately 50%. High growth rates are.
projected to continue for the next few years, as increasing volumes of Internet users use online trading accounts.
Online trading firms such as E-Trade Group, Charles Schwab, and Ameritrade have all experienced significant growth in revenues due to increases in online trading activity. These companies currently offer Internet-based stock trading services, which provide greater convenience and Lower commission rates for many retail investors, compared to traditional securities brokerage services. Many expect online trading to expand to financial products other than equities, such as bonds, foreign°exchange, and financial instrument derivatives.
Financial products such as stocks, bonds, foreign exchange contracts, exchange traded futures and options, as well as contractual assets or liabilities such as reinsurance contracts or interest-rate swaps, all involve some measure of risk. The risks inherent in such products are a fimction of many factors, including the uncertainty of events, such as the Federal Reserve's determination to increase the discount rate, a sudden increase in commodity prices, the change in value of an underlying index such as the Dow Jones Industrial Average, or an overall increase in investor risk aversion. In order to better analyze the nature of such risks, financial economists often treat the real-world financial products as if they were combinations of simpler, hypothetical financial products. These hypothetical financial products typically are designed to pay one unit of currency, say one dollar, to the trader or investor if a particular outcome among a set of possible outcomes occurs. Possible outcomes may be said to fall within "states," which are typically constructed from a distribution of possible outcomes (e.g., the magnitude of the change .in the Federal Reserve discount rate) owing to some real-world event (e.g., a decision of the Federal Reserve regarding the discount rate). In such hypothetical financial products, a set of states is typically chosen so that the states are mutually exclusive and the set collectively covers or exhausts all possible outcomes for the event. This arrangement entails that, by design, exactly one state always occurs based on the event outcome.
_2_ These hypothetical financial products (also known as Arrow-Debreu securities, state securities, or pure securities) are designed to isolate and break-down complex risks into distinct sources, namely, the risk that a distinct state will occur. Such hypothetical financial products are useful since the returns from more complicated securities, including real-world financial products, can be modeled as a linear combination of the returns of the hypothetical financial products. See, ~, R. Merton, Continuous-Time Finance (1990), pp. 441 ff. Thus, such hypothetical financial products are frequently used today to provide the fundamental building ' blocks for analyzing more complex financial products.
In recent years, the growth in derivafives trading has also been enormous.
According to the Federal Reserve, the annualized growth rate in foreign exchange and interest rate derivatives turnover alone is running at about 20%. Corporations, financial institutions, farmers, and even national governments and agencies are all active in the derivatives markets, typically to better manage asset and liability portfolios; hedge financial market risk, and minimize costs of capital funding. Money managers also frequently use derivatives to hedge and undertake economic exposure where there are inherent risks, such as risks of fluctuation in interest rates, foreign exchange rates, convertibility into other securities or outstanding purchase offers for cash or exchange offers for cash or securities.
Derivatives are traded on exchanges, such as the option and futures contracts traded on the Chicago Board of Trade ("CBOT"), as well as off exchange or over-the-counter, ("OTC") . between two or more derivative counterparties. On the major exchanges that operate trading activity in derivatives, orders are typically either transmitted electronically or via open outcry in pits to member brokers who then execute the orders. These member brokers then usually balance or hedge their own portfolio of derivatives to suit their own risk and return criteria. Hedging is customarily accomplished by trading in the derivatives' underlying securities or contracts (e.g., a futures contract in the case of an option on that future) or in similar derivatives (e.g., futures expiring in different calendar months). For OTC derivatives, brokers or dealers customarily seek to balance their active portfolios of derivatives in accordance with the trader's risk management guidelines and profitability criteria.
Broadly speaking then, there are two widely utilized means by which derivatives are currentlyaaded: (1) order-matching and (2) principal market making. Order matching is a model followed by exchanges such as the CBOT or the Chicago Mercantile Exchange and some newer online exchanges. ~In order matching, the exchange coordinates the activities of buyers and sellers so that "bids" to buy (i.e., demand) can be paired off with "offers"
to sell (i:e., supply).
Orders may be matched both electronically and through the primary market making activities of the exchange members. Typically, the exchange itself takes no market risk and covers its own cost of operation by selling memberships to brokers. Member brokers may take principal positions, which are often hedged across their portfolios.
In principal market making, a bank or brokerage firm, for example, establishes a derivatives trading operation, capitalizes it, and makes a market by maintaining a portfolio of derivatives and underlying positions. The market maker usually hedges the portfolio on a dynamic basis by continually changing the composition of the portfolio as market conditions change. In general, the market maker strives to cover its cost of operation by collecting a bid-offer spread and through the scale economies obtained by simultaneously hedging a portfolio of positions. As the market maker takes significant market risk, its counterparties are exposed to the risk that it may go bankrupt. Additionally, while in theory the principal market making activity could be done over a wide area network, in practice derivatives trading is today usually accomplished via the telephone. Often, trades are processed laboriously, with many manual steps required from the front office transaction to the back office processing and clearing.
In theory -- that is, ignoring very real transaction costs (described below) --derivatives trading is, in the language of game theory, a "zero sum" game. One counterparty's gain on a transaction should be exactly offset by the.corresponding counterparty's loss, assuming there are no transaction costs. In fact, it is the zero sum nature of the derivatives market which first allowed the well-known Black-Scholes pricing model to be formulated by noting that a derivative such as an option could be paired with an exactly offsetting position in the underlying security so as to eliminate market risk over short periods of time. It is this "no arbitrage" feature that allows market participants using sophisticated valuation models to mitigate market risk by continually adjusting their portfolios. Stock markets, by contrast, do not have this zero sum feature, as the total stock or value of the market fluctuates due to factors such as interest rates and expected corporate earnings, which are "external" to the market in the sense that they cannot readily be hedged.
The return to a trader of a traditional derivative product is, in most cases, largely determined by the value of the underlying security, asset, liability or claim on which the derivative is based. For example, the value of a call option on a stock, which gives the holder the right to buy the stock at some future date at a fixed strike price, vanes directly with the price of the underlying stock. In the case of non-financial derivatives such as reinsurance contracts, the value of the reinsurance contract is affected by the loss experience on the underlying portfolio of insured claims. The prices of traditional derivative products are usually determined by supply and demand for the derivative based on the value of the underlying security (which is itself usually determined by supply and demand, or, as in the case of insurance, by events insured by the insurance or reinsurance contract).
At present, market-makers can offer derivatives products to their customers in markets where:
Su~cient natural supply and demand exist - Risks are measurable and manageable Sufficient capital has been allocated A failure to satisfy one or more of these conditions in certain capital markets may inhibit new product development, resulting in unsatisfied customer demand.
Currently, the costs of trading derivative securities (both on and off the exchanges) and transferring insurance risk are considered to be high for a number of reasons, including;
(1) Credit Risk: A counterparty to a derivatives (or insurance contract) transaction typically assumes the risk that its counterparty will go bankrupt during the life of the derivatives (or insurance) contract. Margin requirements, credit monitoring, and other contractual devices, which may be costly, are customarily employed to manage derivatives and insurance counterparty credit risk.
(2) Reg_ulatory Requirements: Regulatory bodies, such as the Federal Reserve, Comptroller of the Currency, the Commodities Futures Trading Commission, and international bodies that promulgate regulations affecting global money center banks (e.g., Basle Committee guidelines) generally require institutions dealing in derivatives to meet capital requirements and maintain . risk management systems. These requirements are considered by many to increase the cost of capital and barriers to entry for some entrants into the derivatives trading business, and thus to increase the cost of derivatives transactions for both dealers and end users.
In the United States, state insurance regulations also impose requirements on the operations of insurers, especially in the property-casualty lines where capital demands may be increased by the requirement that insurers reserve for future losses without regard to interest rate discount factors.
(3) Li uidi : Derivatives traders typically hedge their exposures throughout the life of the derivatives contract. Effective hedging usually requires that an active or liquid market exist, throughout the life of the derivative contract, for both the underlying security and the derivative.
Frequently, especially in periods of financial market shocks and disequilibria, liquid markets do not exist to support a well-functioning derivatives market.
(4) Transaction Costs: Dynamic hedging of derivatives often requires continual transactions in the S market over the life of the derivative in order to reduce, eliminate, and manage risk for a derivative or portfolio of derivative securities. This usually means paying bid-offers spreads for each hedging transaction, which can add significantly to the price of the derivative security at inception compared to its theoretical price in absence of the need to pay for such spreads and similar transaction costs.
(5) Settlement and Clearin Costs: The costs of executing, electronically booking, clearing, and settling derivatives transactions can be large, sometimes requiring analytical and database software systems and personnel knowledgeable in such transactions. While a goal of many in the securities processing industry is to achieve "straight-through-processing" of derivatives transactions, many derivatives counterparties continue to manage the processing of these transactions using a combination of electronic and manual steps which are not particularly integrated or automated and therefore add to costs.
(6) Event Risk: Most traders understand effective hedging of derivatives transactions to require markets to be liquid and to exhibit continuously fluctuating prices without sudden and dramatic "gaps." . During periods of financial crises and disequilibria, it is not uncommon to observe 1 dramatic repricing of underlying securities by 50% or more in a period of hours. The event risk of such crises and disequilibria are therefore customarily factored into derivatives prices by dealers, which increases the cost of derivatives in excess of the theoretical prices indicated by derivatives valuation models. These costs are usually spread across all derivatives users.
(7) Model Risk: Derivatives contracts can be quite difficult to value, especially those involving interest rates or features which allow a counterparty to make decisions throughout the life of the derivative (e.g., American options allow a counterparty to realize the value of the derivative at any time during its life). Derivatives dealers will typically add a premium to derivatives prices to insure against the possibility that the valuation models may not adequately reflect market factors or other conditions throughout the life of the contract. In addition, risk management guidelines may require firms to maintain additional capital supporting a derivatives dealing operation where model risk is determined to be a significant factor. Model risk has also been a large factor in well-known cases where complicated securities risk management systems have provided incorrect or incomplete information, such as the Joe Jett/Kidder Peabody losses of 1994.
(8) Asymmetric Information: Derivatives dealers and market makers customarily seek to protect themselves from counterparties with superior information. Bid-offer spreads for derivatives S therefore usually reflect a built-in insurance premium for the dealer for transactions with counterparties with superior information, which can lead to unprofitable transactions. Traditional insurance markets also incur costs due to asymmetric information. In property-casualty lines, the direct writer of the insurance almost always has superior information regarding the book of risks than does the assuming reinsurer. Much like the market maker in capital markets, the reinsurer typically prices its informational disadvantage into the reinsurance premiums.
(9) Incomplete Markets: Traditional capital and insurance markets are often viewed as incomplete in the sense that the span of contingent claims is limited,.i.e., the markets may not provide opportunities to hedge all of the risks for which hedging opportunities are sought. As a .
consequence, participants typically either bear risk inefficiently or use less than optimal means to transfer or hedge against risk. For example, the demand by some investors to hedge inflation risk has resulted in the issuance by some governments of inflation-linked bonds which have coupons and principal amounts linked to Consumer Price Index (CPI) levels. This provides a degree of insurance against inflation risk. However, holders of such bonds frequently make assumptions as to the future relationship between real and nominal interest rates. An imperfect correlation between the contingent claim (in this case, inflation-linked bond) and the contingent event (inflation) gives rise to what traders call "basis risk," which is risk that, in today's markets, cannot be perfectly insured or hedged.
Currently, transaction costs are also considerable in traditional insurance and reinsurance markets. In recent years, considerable effort has been expended in attempting to securitize insurance risk such as property-casualty catastrophe risk. Traditional insurance and reinsurance markets in many respects resemble principal market-maker securities markets and suffer from many of the same shortcomings and incur similar costs of operation. Typically, risk is physically transferred contractually, credit status of counterparties is monitored, and sophisticated risk management systems are deployed and maintained. Capitalization levels to support insurance portfolios of risky assets and liabilities may be dramatically out of equilibrium at any given time due to price stickiness, informational asymmetries and costs, and regulatory constraints. In short, the insurance and reinsurance markets tend to operate according to the same market mechanisms _7_ that have prevailed for decades, despite large market shocks such as the Lloyds crisis in the late 1980's and early 1990's.
Accordingly, a driving force behind all the contributors to the costs of derivatives and insurance contracts is the necessity or desirability of risk management through dynamic hedging or contingent claim replication in continuous, liquid, and informationally fair markets. Hedging is used by derivatives dealers to reduce their exposure to excessive market risk while making transaction fees to cover their cost of capital and ongoing operations; and effective hedging requires liquidity.
Recent patents have addressed the problem of financial market liquidity in the context of an electronic order-matching systems (e.g., U.S. Pat. No. 5,845,266). The principal techniques disclosed to enhance liquidity are to increase participation and traded volume in the system and to solicit trader preferences about combinations of price and quantity for a particular trade of a security. There are shortcomings to these techniques, however. First, these techniques implement order-matching and limit order book algorithms, which can be and are effectively employed in traditional "brick and mortar" exchanges. Their electronic implementation, however, primarily serves to save on transportation and telecommunication charges: No .
fundamental change is contemplated to market structure for which an electronic network may be essential. Second, the disclosed techniques appear to enhance liquidity at the expense of placing large informational burdens on the traders (by soliciting preferences, for example, over an entire price-quantity demand curve) and by introducing uncertainty as to the exact price at. which a trade has been transacted or is "filled." Finally, these electronic order matching systems contemplate a traditional counterparty pairing, which means physical securities are frequently transferred, cleared, and settled after the counterparties are identified and matched. In other words, techniques disclosed in the context of electronic order-matching systems are technical elaborations to the basic problem of how to optimize the process of matching arrays of bids and offers.
Patents relating to derivatives, such as U.S. Patent No. 4,903,201, disclose an electronic adaptation of current open-outcry or order matching exchanges for the trading of futures is disclosed. Another recent patent, U.S. Pat. No. 5,806,048, relates to the creation of open-end mutual fund derivative securities to provide enhanced liquidity and improved availability of information affecting pricing. This patent, however, does not contemplate an electronic derivatives exchange which requires the traditional hedging or replicating portfolio approach to _g_ synthesizing the financial derivatives. Similarly, U.S. Pat. No. 5,794,207 proposes an electronic means of matching buyers' bids and sellers' offers, without explaining the nature of the economic price equilibria achieved through such a market process.
SZfMMARY OF THE INVENTION
The present invention is directed to systems and methods of trading, and financial products, having a goal of reducing transaction costs for market participants who hedge against or otherwise make investments in contingent claims relating to events of economic significance:
The claims are contingent in that their payout or return depends on the outcome of an observable event with more than one possible outcome. An example of such a contingent claim is a digital option, such as a digital call option, where the investor receives a payout if the underlying asset, stock or index expires at or above a specified strike price and receives no payout if the underlying asset, stock or other index expires below the strike price. Digital options can also be referred to as; for example, "binary options" and "all or nothing options."
The contingent claims relate to events of economic significance in that an investor or trader in a contingent claim typically is not economically indifferent to the outcome of the event; even if the investor or trader.
has not invested in or traded a contingent claim relating to the event.
Intended users of preferred and other embodiments of the present invention are typically institutional investors, such as financial institutions including banks, investment banks, primary insurers and reinsurers, and corporate treasurers, hedge funds and pension fluids. Users can also include any individual or entity with a need for risk allocation services. As used in this specification, the terms "user," "trader" and "investor" are used interchangeably to mean any institution, individual or entity that desires to trade or invest in contingent claims or other financial products described in this specification.
The contingent claims pertaining to an event have a trading period or an auction period in order to finalize a return for each defined state, each defined state corresponding to an outcome or set of outcomes for the event, and another period for observing the event upon which the contingent claim is based. When the contingent claim is a digital option, the price or investment amount for each digital option is finalized at the end of the trading period, along with the return for each defined state. The entirety of trades or orders placed and accepted with respect to a certain trading period are processed in a demand-based market or auction. The organization or institution, individual or other entity sponsoring, running, maintaining or operating the demand--9_ based market or auction, can be referred to, for example, as an "exchange,"
"auction sponsor"
and/or "market sponsor."
In each market or auction, the returns to the contingent claims adjust during the trading period of the market or auction with changes in the distribution of amounts invested in each of the states. The investment amounts for the contingent claims can either be provided up front or determined during the trading period with changes in the distribution of desired returns and selected outcomes for each claim. The returns payable for each of the states are finalized after-the conclusion of each relevant trading period. In a preferred embodiment, the total amount invested, less a transaction fee to an exchange, or a market or auction sponsor, is equal to the total amount of the payouts. In other words, in theory, the returns on all of the contingent claims established during a particular trading period and pertaining to a particular event are essentially ' zero sum, as are the traditional derivatives markets. In one embodiment, the investment amounts or prices for each contingent claim are finalized after the conclusiowof each relevant trading period, along with the returns payable for each of the states. Since the total amount invested, less 15. a transaction fee to an exchange, or a.market or auction sponsor, is equal to the total amount of payouts, an optimization solution using an iteration. algorithm described below can be used to determine the equilibrium investment amounts or prices for each contingent claim along with establishing the returns on all of the contingent claims; given the desired or requested return for each claim; the selection of outcomes for each claim and the limit (if any) on the investment : amount for each claim.
The process by which returns and investment amounts for each contingent claim are finalized in the present invention is demand-based, and does not in any substantial way depend on supply. By contrast, traditional markets set prices through the interaction of supply and demand by crossing bids to buy and offers to sell ("bid/offer"). The demand-based contingent : claim mechanism of the present invention sets returns by financing returns to successful investments with losses from unsuccessful investments. Thus, in a preferred embodiment, the returns to successful investments (as well as the prices or investment amounts for investments in digital options) are determined by the total and relative amounts of all investments placed on each of the defined states for the specified observable event.
As used in this specification, the term "contingent claim" shall have the meaning customarily ascribed to it in the securities, trading, insurance and economics communities.
"Contingent claims" thus include, for example, stocks, bonds and other such securities, derivative _10_ JGl:llilLleS, insurance contracts and reinsurance agreements, and any other financial products, instruments, contracts, assets, or liabilities whose value depends upon or reflects economic risk due to the occurrence of future, real-world events. These events may be financial-related events, such as changes in interest rates, or non-financial-related events such as changes in weather conditions, demand for electricity, and fluctuations in real estate prices.
Contingent claims also include all economic or financial interests, whether already traded or not yet traded, which have or reflect inherent risk or uncertainty due to the occurrence of future zeal-world events.
Examples of contingent claims of economic or financial interest which are not yet traded on traditional markets are financial products having values that vary with the fluctuations in corporate earnings or changes in real estate values and rentals. The term "contingent claim" as used in this specification encompasses both hypothetical financial products of the Arrow-Debreu variety, as well as any risky asset, contract or product which can'be expressed as a combination or portfolio of the hypothetical financial products.
For the purposes of this specification, an "investment" in or "trade" or an "order" of a contingent claim is the act of putting an amount (in the units of value defined by the contingent claim) at risk, with a financial return depending on the outcome of an event of economic significance underlying the group of contingent claims pertaining to that event.
"Derivative security" (used interchangeably with "derivative") also has a meaning customarily ascribed to it in the securities, trading, insurance and economics communities. This includes a security or contract whose value depends on such factors as the value of an underlying security, index, asset or liability, or on a feature of such an underlying security, such as interest rates or convertibility into some other security: A derivative security is one example of a contingent claim as defined above. Financial futures on stock indices such as the S&P S00 or options to buy and sell such futures contracts are highly popular exchange-traded financial derivatives. An interest-rate swap, which is an example of an off exchange derivative, is an agreement between two counterparties to exchange series of cashflows based on underlying factors, such as the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) quoted daily in London for a large number of foreign currencies. Like the exchange-traded futures and options, off exchange agreements can fluctuate in value with the underlying factors to which they are linked or derived.
Derivatives may also be traded on commodities, insurance events, and other events, such as the weather.
_ii_ In this specification, the fimction for computing and allocating returns to contingent claims is termed the Demand Reallocation Function (DRF). A DRF is demand-based and involves reallocating returns to investments in each state after the outcome of the observable event is known .in order to compensate successful investments from losses on unsuccessful S investments (after any transaction or exchange fee). Since an adjustable return based on variations in amounts invested is a key aspect of the invention, contingent claims implemented-using a DRF will be referred to as demand-based adjustable return (DBAR) contingent claims.
In accordance with embodiments of the present invention, an Order Price Function (OPF) is a fimction for computing the investment amounts or prices for contingent claims which are 1Q digital options. 'An OPF, which includes the DRF, is also demand-based and involves determining the prices for each digital option at the end of the trading period, but before the outcome of the observable event is known. The OPF determines the prices as a function of the outcomes selected in each digital option (corresponding to the states selected by a trader for the digital option to be in-the-money), the requested payout for the digital option if the option expires 1 S in-the money, and the limit placed on the price. (if any) when the order for the option is placed in the market .or auction.
"Demand-based market," "demand-based -auction" may include, for example; a market or auction which is run or executed according to the principles set forth in the embodiments of the present invention. "Demand-based technology" .may include, for example, technology used to 20 run or execute orders in a demand-based market or auction in accordance with the principles set forth in the embodiments of the present invention. "Contingent claims" or "DBAR contingent claims" may include, for example, contingent claims that are processed in a demand-based market or auction. ."Contingent claims" or "DBAR contingent claims" may include, for example, digital options or DBAR digital options, discussed in this specification. With respect to digital 25 options, demand-based markets may include,. for example, DBAR DOES (DBAR
Digital Option Exchanges), or exchanges in which orders for digital options or DBAR digital options are placed and processed. "Contingent claims" or "DBAR contingent claims" may also include, for example, DBAR-enabled products or DBAR-enabled financial products, discussed in this specification.
30 Preferred features of a trading system for a group of DBAR contingent claims (i:e:, group of claims pertaining to the same event) include the following: (1) an entire distribution of states is open for investment, not just a single price as in the traditional markets;
(2) returns are adjustable and determined mathematically based on invested amounts in each of the states available for investment, (3) invested amounts are preferably non-decreasing (as explained below), providing a commitment of offered liquidity to the market over the distribution of states, and in one embodiment of the present invention, adjustable and determined mathematically based on requested returns per order, selection of outcomes for the option to expire in-the-money, and limit amounts (if any), and (4) information is available in real-time across the distribution of states, including, in particular, information on the amounts invested across the distribution of all states (commonly known as a "limit order book"). . Other.consequences of preferred embodiments of the present invention include (1) elimination of order-matching or crossing of the .bid and offer sides of the market; (2) reduction of the need for a market maker to conduct dynamic hedging and risk management; (3) more opportunities for hedging and insuring events of economic significance (i.e., greater market "completeness"); and (4) the ability to offer investments in contingent claims whose profit and loss scenarios are comparable to these for digital options or other derivatives in traditional markets, but can be implemented using the DBAR systems and methods of the present invention, for example without the need for sellers of such options or derivatives as they fimction in conventional markets.
Other preferred embodiments of the present invention can accommodate realization.of profits and losses by traders at multiple points before all of the criteria for terminating a group of contingent claims are known. This is accomplished by.arranging a plurality of trading periods, .
each.having its own set of finalized returns. Profit or loss can be realized or "locked-in" at the end of each trading period, as opposed to waiting for the final outcome of the event on which the relevant contingent claims are based. Such lock-in can be achieved by placing hedging investments in' successive trading periods as the returns change, or adjust, from period to period.
In this way, profit and loss can be realized on an evolving basis (limited only by the frequency and length of the periods),' enabling traders to achieve the same or perhaps higher frequency of trading and hedging than available in traditional markets.
If.desired, an issuer such as a corporation, investment bank, underwriter or other financial intermediary can create a security having returns that are driven in a comparable manner to the DBAR contingent claims of the present invention. For example, a corporation may issue a bond with returns that are linked to insurance risk. The issuer can solicit trading and calculate the returns based on the amounts invested in contingent claims corresponding to each level or state of insurance risks.
-ll3-In a preferred embodiment of the present invention, changes in the return for investments in one state will affect the return on investments in another state in the same distribution of states for a group of contingent claims. Thus, traders' returns will depend not only on the actual outcome of a real-world, observable event but also on trading choices from among the distribution of states made by other traders. This aspect of DBAR markets, in which returns for one state are affected by changes in investments in another state in the same distribution, allows for the elimination of order-crossing and dynamic market maker hedging. Price-discovery in preferred embodiments of the present invention can be supported by a one-way market (i.e., demand, not supply) for DBAR contingent claims. By structuring derivatives and insurance trading according to DBAR principles, the high costs of traditional order matching and principal market making market structures can be reduced substantially. Additionally, a market implemented by systems and methods of the present invention is especially amenable to electronic operation over a wide network, such as the Internet.
In its preferred embodiments, the present invention mitigates derivatives transaction costs 1 S found in traditional markets due to dynamic hedging and order matching. A
preferred embodiment of the present invention provides a system for trading contingent claims structured under DBAR principles, in which amounts invested in on each state in a group of DBAR
contingent claims are reallocated from unsuccessful investments, under defined rules, to successful investments after the deduction of exchange transaction fees. In particular, the operator of such. a system or exchange provides the physical plant and electronic infrastructure for trading to be conducted, collects and aggregates investments (or in one embodiment, first collects and aggregates investment information to determine investment amounts per trade or order and then collects and aggregates the investment amounts), calculates the retains that result from such inveshnents, and then allocates to the successful investments retains that are financed by the unsuccessful investments, after deducting a transaction fee for the operation of the system.
In preferred embodiments, where the successful investments are financed with the losses from unsuccessful investments, returns on all trades are correlated and traders make investments against each other as well as assuming the risk of chance outcomes. All traders for a group of DBAR contingent claims depending on a given event become counterparties to each other, leading to a mutualization of financial interests. Furthermore, in preferred embodiments of the present invention, projected returns prevailing at the time an investment is made may not be the same as the final payouts or returns after the outcome of the relevant event is known.
-g Traditional derivatives markets by contrast, operate largely under a house "banking"
system. In this system, the market-maker, which typically has the function of matching buyers and sellers, customarily quotes a price at which ar.~investor may buy or sell.
If a given investor buys or sells at the price, the investor's ultimate return is based upon this price, i.e., the price at which the investor later sells or buys the original position, along with the original price at which the position was traded, will determine the investor's return. As the market-maker may not be able perfectly to offset buy and sell orders at all times or may desire to maintain a degree of risk in the expectation of returns, it will frequently be subject to varying degrees of market risk (as well as credit risk, in some cases). In a traditional derivatives market, market-makers which . ' ' match buy and sell orders typically rely upon actuarial advantage, bid-offer spreads, a large.
capital base, and "coppering" or hedging (risk management) to minimize the chance of .
bankruptcy due to such market risk exposures.
Each trader in a house banking system typically has only a single counterparty -- the market-maker, exchange, or trading counterparty (in the case, for example, of over-the-counter 1S derivatives). By contrast, because a market in DBAR contingent claimsmay operate according to principles whereby unsuccessful investments finance the returns on successful investments, the exchange itself is exposed to reduced risk of loss and therefore has reduced need to transact in the market to hedge itself. . In preferred embodiments of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention, dynamic hedging or bid-offer crossing by the exchange is generally not required, and . the probability of the exchange or market-maker going bankrupt may be reduced essentially to zero'. Such a system distributes the risk of bankruptcy away from the exchange or market-maker and among all the traders in the system. The system as a whole provides a great degree of self hedging and substantial reduction of the risk of market failure for reasons related to market risk.
A DBAR contingent claim exchange or market or auction may also be "self clearing" and require little clearing infrastructure (such as clearing agents, custodians, nostro/vostro bank accounts, and transfer and register agents). A derivatives trading system or exchange or market or auction structured according to DBAR contingent claim principles therefore offers many advantages over current derivatives markets governed by house banking principles.
The present invention also differs from electronic or parimutuel betting systems disclosed in the prior art (e.g., U.S. Patent Nos. 5,873,782 and 5,749,785). In betting systems or games of chance, in the absence of a wager the bettor is economically indifferent to the outcome (assuming the bettor does not own the casino or the racetrack or breed the racing horses, for example). The difference between games of chance and events of economic significance is well known and understood in financial markets.
In summary, the present invention provides systems and methods for conducting demand-based trading. A preferred embodiment of a method of the present invention for conducting demand-based trading includes the steps of (a) establishing a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to at least one possible outcome of an event of economic significance; (b) accepting investments of value units by a plurality of traders in the defined states; and (c) allocating a payout to each investment. The allocating step is responsive to the total.number of value units invested in the defined states, the relative number of value units invested in each of the defined states, and the identification of the defined state that occurred upon fulfillment of all of the termination criteria:.
An additional preferred embodiment of a method for conducting demand-based trading also includes establishing, accepting, and allocating steps. The establishing.step in this embodiment includes establishing a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria. Each of the defined states corresponds to a possible state of a selected financial product when each of the termination criteria is fulfilled. The accepting step includes accepting investments of value units by multiple traders in the defined states. The allocating step includes allocating a payout .to each investment. This allocating step is responsive to the total number of value units invested in the defined states, the relative number of value units invested in each of the defined states, and the identification of the defined state that occurred upon fulfillment of all of the termination criteria.
In preferred embodiments of a method for conducting demand=based trading of the present invention, the payout to each investment in each of the defined states that did not occur upon fulfillment of all of the termination criteria is zero, and the sum of the payouts to all of the investments is not greater than the value of the total number of the value units invested in the defined states. In a fiuther preferred embodiment, the sum of the values of the payouts to all of the investments is equal to the value of all of the value units invested in defined states, less a fee.
In preferred embodiments of a method for conducting demand-based trading, at least one investment of value units designates a set of defined states and a desired return-on-investment from the designated set of defined states. In these preferred embodiments, the allocating step is further responsive to the desired return-on-investment from the designated set of defined states.

In another preferred embodiment of a method for conducting demand-based trading, the method further includes the step of calculating Capital-At-Risk for at least one investment of value units by at least one trader. In alternative fixrther preferred embodiments, the step of calculating Capital-At-Risk includes the use of the Capital-At-Risk Value-At-Risk method, the Capital-At-Risk Monte Carlo Simulation method, or the Capital-At-Risk Historical Simulation method.
In preferred embodiments of a method for conducting demand-based trading, the method further includes the step of calculating Credit-Capital-At-Risk for at..least one investment of value units by at least one trader. In alternative further preferred embodiments, the step of calculating Credit-Capital-At-Risk includes the use of the Credit-Capital-At-Risk Value-At-Risk method, the Credit-Capital-At-Risk Monte Carlo Simulation method, or the Credit-Capital-At-Risk Historical Simulation method.
In preferred embodiments of a method for conducting demand-based trading of the present invention, at .least one investment of value units is a mufti-state investment that designates a set of defined states. In a fiirther preferred embodiment, at least one mufti-state investment designates a set of desired returns that is responsive to the designated set of defined states, and he allocating step is further responsive to the set of desired returns. In a further preferred embodiment, each desired return of the set of desired returns is responsive to a subset of the designated set of defined states. In an alternative preferred embodiment, the set of desired returns approximately corresponds to expected returns from a set of defined states of a prespecified investment vehicle such as, for example, a particular call option.
In preferred embodiments of a method for conducting demand-based trading of the present invention, the allocating step includes the steps of (a) calculating the required number of value units of the mufti-state investment that designates a set of desired returns, and (b) distributing the value units of the mufti-state investment that designates a set of desired returns to the plurality of defined states. 1n a further preferred embodiment, the allocating step includes the step of solving a set of simultaneous equations that relate traded amounts to unit payouts and payout distributions; and the calculating step and the distributing step are responsive to the solving step.
In preferred embodiments of a method for conducting demand-based trading of the present invention, the solving step includes the step of fixed point iteration. In further preferred embodiments, the step of fixed point iteration includes the steps of (a) selecting an equation of the set of simultaneous equations described above, the equation having an independent variable and at least one dependent variable; (b) assigning arbitrary values to each of the dependent variables in the selected equation; (c) calculating the value of the independent variable in the selected equation responsive to the currently assigned values of each the dependent variables; (d) assigning the calculated value of the independent variable to the independent variable; (e) designating an equation of the set of simultaneous equations as the selected equation; and (f) sequentially performing the calculating the value step, the assigning the calculated value step, and the designating an equation step until the value of each of the variables converges.
A preferred embodiment of a method for estimating state probabilities in a demand-based '. trading method of the present invention includes the steps of (a) performing a demand-based trading method having a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein an investment of value units by each of a plurality of traders is accepted in at least one of the defined states, and at least one of these defined states corresponds to at least one possible outcome of an event of economic significance; (b) monitoring the relative, number of value units invested in each of the defined states; and (c) estimating, responsive to the monitoring step, the probabilityahat a selected defined state will be the defined state that occurs upon fulfillinent of all of the termination criteria.
An additional preferred embodiment of a method for estimating state probabilities in a demand-based tradingmethod also includes performing; monitoring, and estimating steps. The performing step includes performing a demand-based trading method having a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein an investment of value units by each of a plurality of traders is accepted in at least one of the defined states; and .
wherein each of the defined states corresponds to a possible state of a selected financial product when each of the termination criteria is fulfilled. The monitoring step includes monitoring the relative number of value units invested in each of the defined states. The estimating step includes estimating, responsive to the monitoring step, the probability that a selected defined state will be the defined state that occurs upon fulfillment of all of the termination criteria.
A preferred embodiment of a method for promoting liquidity in a demand-based trading method of the present invention includes the step of performing a demand-based trading method having a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein an investment of value units by each of a plurality of traders is accepted in at least one of the defined states and wherein any investment of value units cannot be withdrawn after acceptance.
_ 1g _ Each of the defined states corresponds to at least one possible outcome of an event of economic significance. A further preferred embodiment of a method for promoting liquidity in a demand based trading method includes the step of hedging. The hedging step includes the hedging of a trader's previous investment of value units by making a new investment of value units in one or more'of the defined states not invested in by the previous investment.
An additional preferred embodiment of a method for promoting liquidity in a demand-based trading method includes the step of performing a demand-based trading method having a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein an investment of value units by each of a plurality of traders is accepted.in at least one of the defined states and wherein any investment of value units cannot be withdrawn after acceptance, and each of the defined states corresponds to a possible state of a selected financial product when each of the termination criteria is fulfilled. A further preferred~embodiment of such a method for promoting liquidity in a demand-based trading method includes the.step of hedging. The.
hedging step includes the hedging of a trader's previous investment of value units by making a 1 S new investment of value units in one or more of the defined states not invested in by the previous investment.
A preferred embodiment of a method for conducting quasi-continuous demand-based trading includes the steps of (a) establishing a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to at least one possible outcome of an event; (b) conducting a plurality of trading cycles, wherein each trading cycle includes the step of accepting, during a predefined trading period and prior to the fulfillment of all of the termination criteria, an investment of value units by each of a plurality of traders in at least one of the defined states; and (c) allocating a payout to each investment. The allocating step is responsive to the total 'number of the value units invested in the defined states during each of the trading periods, the relative number of the value units invested in each of the defined states during each of the trading periods, and an identification of the defined state that occurred upon fulfillment of all of the termination criteria. In a further preferred embodiment of a method for conducting quasi-continuous demand-based trading, the predefined trading periods are sequential and do not overlap.
Another preferred embodiment of a method for conducting demand-based trading includes the steps of (a) establishing a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to one possible outcome of an - fi9-event of economic significance (or a financial instrument); (b) accepting, prior to fulfillment of all of the termination criteria, an investment of value units by each of a plurality of traders in at least one of the plurality of defined states, with at least one investment designating a range of possible outcomes corresponding to a set of defined states; and (c) allocating a payout to each investment. In such a preferred embodiment, the allocating step is responsive to the total number of value units in the plurality of defined states, the relative number of value units invested in each of the defined states, and an identification of the defined state that occurred upon the fulfillment of all of the termination criteria. Also in such a preferred embodiment, the allocation is done so that substantially the same payout is allocated to each state of the set of defined states. This embodiment contemplates, among other implementations, a market or exchange for contingent claims of the present invention that provides -- without traditional sellers --profit and loss scenarios comparable to those expected by traders in derivative securities known as digital-options, where payout is the same if the option'expires anywhere in the money, and where there is no payout if the option expires out of the money.
Anotherpreferred embodiment of the present invention provides a method for conducting demand-based trading including: (a) establishing a plurality of defined states and a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to one possible outcome of an event of economic significance (or a financial instrument); (b) accepting, prior to fulfillment of all of the termination criteria, a conditional investment order by a trader in at least one of the plurality of defined states; (c) computing, prior to fulfillment of all of the termination criteria a probability corresponding to each defined state; and (d) executing or withdrawing, prior to the fulfillinent of all of the termination criteria, the conditional investment responsive to the computing step. In such embodiments, the computing step is responsive to the total number of value units invested in the plurality of defined states and the relative number of value units invested in each of the plurality of defined states. Such embodiments contemplate, among other implementations, a market or exchange (again without traditional sellers) in which investors can make and execute conditional or limit orders, where an order is executed or withdrawn in response to a calculation of a probability of the occurrence of one or more of the defined states. Preferred embodiments of the system of the present invention involve the use of electronic technologies, such as computers, computerized databases and telecommunications systems, to implement methods for conducting demand-based trading of the present invention.
_2~_ A preferred embodiment of a system of the present invention for conducting demand-based trading includes (a) means for accepting, prior to the fulfilhnent of all predetermined terniination criteria, investments of value units by a plurality of traders in at least one of a plurality of defined states, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to at least one possible outcome of an event of economic significance; and (b) means for allocating a payout to each investment. This allocation is responsive to the total .number of value units invested in the defined states, the relative number of value units invested in each of the defined states, and the identification of the defined state that occurred upon fulfillment of all of the termination criteria.
An additional preferred embodiment of a system of the present invention for conducting demand-based trading includes (a) means for accepting, prior to the fulfillment of all predetermined-termination criteria, investments of value units by a plurality of traders in at least one of a plurality of defined states, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to a possible state of a selected financial product when each of the termination criteria is fulfilled; and (b) means for allocating a payout to each investment. This allocation is responsive to the total number of value units invested in the defined states, the relative.number of value units invested in each of the defined states, and the identification of the defined state that occurred upon fulfillment of all of the termination criteria.
A preferred embodiment of a demand-based trading apparatus of the present invention includes (a) an interface processor communicating with a plurality of traders and a market data system; and (b) a demand-based transaction processor, communicating with the interface.
processor and having a trade status database. The demand-based transaction processor maintains;
responsive to. the market data system and to a demand=based transaction with one of the plurality of traders, the trade status database, and processes, responsive to the trade status database, the .
demand-based transaction.
In fiuther preferred embodiments of a demand-based trading apparatus of the present invention, maintaining the trade status database includes (a) establishing a contingent claim having a plurality of defined states, a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, and at least one trading period, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to at least one possible outcome of an event of economic significance; (b) recording, responsive to the demand-based transaction, an investment of value units by one of the plurality of traders in at least one of the plurality of defined states; (c) calculating, responsiveao the total number of the value units invested in the plurality of defined states during each trading period and responsive to the relative _21 _ number of the value units invested in each of the plurality of defined states during each trading period, finalized returns at the end of each trading period; and (d) determining, responsive to an identification of the defined state that occurred upon the fulfillment of all of the termination criteria and to the finalized returns, payouts to each of the plurality of traders; and processing the demand-based transaction includes accepting, during the trading period, the investment of value units by one of the plurality of traders in at least one of the plurality of defined states;
In an alternative fiuther preferred embodiment of a demand-based trading apparatus of the present invention, maintaining the trade status database includes (a) establishing a contingent claim having a plurality of defined states, a plurality of predetermined termination criteria, and at .
least one trading period, wherein each of the defined states corresponds to a possible state of a selected financial product when each of the termination criteria is fulfilled;
(b) recording, responsive to the demand-based transaction, an investment of value units by one of the plurality of traders in at least one of the plurality of defined states; (c) calculating, responsive to the total number of the value units invested in the plurality of defined states during each trading period 1 S and responsive to the relative number of the value units invested in each of the plurality of defined states during each trading period, finalized returns at the end of each trading period; and (d) determining, responsive to an identification of the defined.state that occurred upon the fulfillment of all~of the termination criteria and to the finalized returns, payouts to each of the plurality of traders; and processing the demand-based transaction includes accepting, during the trading period, the investment of value units by one of the plurality of traders in at least one of the plurality of defined states;
1n fiuther preferred embodiments of a demand-based trading apparatus of the present invention, maintaining the trade status database includes calculating return estimates; and processing the demand-based transaction includes providing, responsive to the demand-based transaction, the return estimates.
In fixrther preferred embodiments of a demand-based trading apparatus of the present invention, maintaining the trade status database includes calculating risk estimates; and processing the demand-based transaction includes providing, responsive to the demand-based transaction, the risk estimates.
In fiwther preferred embodiments of a demand=based trading apparatus of the present invention, the demand-based transaction includes a mufti-state investment that specifies a desired payout distribution and a set of constituent states; and maintaining the trade status database includes allocating, responsive to the multi-state investment, value units to the set of constituent states to create the desired payout distribution. Such demand-based transactions may also include mufti-state investments that specify the same payout if any of a designated set of states occurs upon fulfillinent of the termination criteria. Other demand-based transactions executed by the demand-based trading apparatus of the present invention include conditional investments in one or more states, where the investment is executed or withdrawn in response to a calculation of a probability of the occurrence of one or more states upon the fi~lfillment of the termination criteria.
In an additional embodiment, systems and methods for conducting demand-based trading includes the steps of (a) establishing a plurality of states, each state corresponding to at least one possible outcome of an event of economic significance; (b) receiving an indication of a desired payout and an indication of a selected outcomes the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of the plurality of states; and (c) determining an investment amount as a function of the selected outcome, the desired payout and a total amount invested in the plurality of states.
1 S In another additional embodiment, systems and methods for conducting demand-based trading includes the steps of (a) establishing a plurality of states, each state corresponding to at least one possible outcome of an event (whether or not such event is an economic event); (b) receiving an indication of a desired payout and an indication of a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of the plurality of states; and (c) determining an investment amount as a fimction of the selected outcome, the desired payout and a total amount invested in the plurality of states.
In another additional embodiment, systems and methods for conducting demand-based trading includes the steps of (a) establishing a plurality of states, each state corresponding to at least one possible outcome of an event of economic significance; (b) receiving an indication of an investment amount and a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of the plurality of states; and (c) determining a payout as a fimction of the investment amount, the selected outcome, a total amount invested in the plurality of states, and an identification of at least one state corresponding to an observed outcome of the event.
In another additional embodiment, systems and methods for conducting demand-based trading include the steps of (a) receiving an indication of one or more parameters of a financial product or derivatives strategy; and (b) determining one or more of a selected outcome, a desired payout, an investment amount, and a limit on the investment amount for each contingent claim in a set of one or more contingent claims as a function of the one or more financial product or derivatives strategy parameters.
In another additional embodiment, systems and methods for conducting demand-based trading include the steps of (a) receiving an indication of one or more parameters of a financial product or derivatives strategy; and (b) determining an investment amount and a selected outcome for each contingent claim in a set of one or more contingent claims as a fiuiction of the one or more financial product or derivatives strategy parameters.
In another additional embodiment, a demand-enabled financial product for trading in a demand-based auction includes a set of one or more contingent claims, the set approximating or replicating a financial product or derivatives strategy, each contingent claim in the set having an investment amount and a selected outcome, each investment amount being dependent upon one or more parameters of a financial product or derivatives strategy and a total amount invested in the auction.
In another additional embodiment, methods for conducting demand-based trading on at least one event includes the steps of (a) determining one or more parameters of a contingent claim, in a replication set of one or more contingent claims, as a fimction of one or more parameters of a derivatives strategy and an. outcome of the event; and (b) determining an investment amount for a contingent claim in the replication set as a fimction of one or more parameters of the derivatives strategy and an outcome of the event.
In another additional embodiment, methods for conducting demand based trading include the steps of enabling one or more derivatives strategies and/or financial products to be traded in a demand-based auction; and offering and/or trading one or more of the enabled derivatives strategies and enabled financial products to customers.
In another additional embodiment, methods for conducting derivatives trading include the steps of receiving an indication of one or more parameters of a derivatives strategy on one or more events of economic significance; and determining one or more parameters of each digital in a replication set made up of one or more digitals as a function of one or more parameters of the derivatives strategy.
In another additional embodiment, methods for trading contingent claims in a demand-based auction, includes the step of approximating or replicating a contingent claim with a set of demand-based claims. The set of demand-based claims includes at least one vanilla option, thus defining a vanilla replicating basis.
_2~_ In another additional embodiment, methods for trading contingent claims in a demand=
based auction on an event, includes the step of determining a value of a contingent claim as a function o1' a demand-based valuation of each vanilla option in a replication set for the contingent claim. The replication set includes at least one vanilla option, thus defining another vanilla replicating basis.
In another additional embodiment, methods for conducting a demand-based auction on an event, includes the steps of establishing a plurality of strikes for the auction, each strike corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; establishing a plurality of replicating claims for the auction, one or more replicating claims striking at each strike in the plurality of strikes;
replicating a contingent claim with a replication set including one or.more of the replicating claims; and determining the price and/or payout of the contingent claim as a function of a demand-based valuation of each of the replicating claims in the replication set.
In another additional embodiment, methods for processing a customer order for one or more derivatives strategies, in a demand-based. auction on~an event, where the auction includes one or more customer orders are described as including the steps of establishing strikes for the auction, each one of the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome.of the event; establishing replicating claims for the auction, one or more replicating claims striking at each strike in the auction; replicating each derivatives strategy in the customer order with a replication set including one or more of the replicating claims in the auction; and determining a premium for the customer order by engaging in a demand-based valuation of each one of the replicating claims in the replication set for each one of the derivatives strategies in the customer order.
In another additional embodiment, a method for investing. in a demand-based auction on an event, includes the steps of providing an indication of one or more selected strikes and a payout profile for one or more derivatives strategies, each of the selected strikes corresponding to a selected outcome of the event, and each of the selected strikes being selected from a plurality of strikes established for the auction, each of the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; receiving an indication of a price for each of the derivatives strategies, the price being determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating the derivatives strategy, the replication set including one or more replicating claims from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, at least one of each of the replicating claims in the auction striking at one of the strikes.

In another additional embodiment, a computer system for processing a customer order for one or more derivatives strategy, in a demand-based auction on an event, the auction including one or more customer orders, the computer system including one or more processors that are configured to: establish strikes for the auction, each one of the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; establish replicating claims for the auction, one or more replicating claims striking at each one of the strikes; and replicate each of the derivatives strategies in the customer order with a replication set including one or more of the replicating claims in the auction; and determine a premium for the customer order by engaging in a demand-based valuation of each one of the replicating claims in the replication set for each one of the derivatives strategies in the customer order.
In another additional embodiment, a computer system for placing an order to invest in a demand-based auction on an event, the order including one or more derivatives strategies, the computer system including one or more processors configured to: provide an indication of one or more selected strikes and a payout profile for each derivatives strategy, each selected strike corresponding to a selected outcome of the event, and each selected strike being selected from a plurality of strikes established for the auction, each of.the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; receive an indication of a premium:for the order, the premium of the order being determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating each derivatives strategy in the order, the replication set including one or more replicating claims from ' a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction,. with one or more of the replicating claims in the auction striking at each of the strikes.
In another additional embodiment, a method for executing a trade includes the steps of receiving a request for an order, the request indicating one or more selected strikes and a payout profile for one or more derivatives strategies in the order, each selected strike corresponding to a : selected outcome of the event, and each selected strike being selected from a plurality of strikes established for the auction, each of the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event;
providing an indication of a premium for the order, the premium being determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating each derivatives strategy in the order, the replication set including one or more replicating claims from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, one or more of each of the replicating claims in the auction striking at each of the strikes; and receiving an indication of a decision to place the order for the determined premium.
_2~_ In another additional embodiment, a method for providing financial advice, includes the steps of providing a person with advice about investing in one or more of a type of derivatives strategy in a demand-based auction, an order for the one or more derivatives strategies indicating one or more selected strikes and a payout profile for the derivatives strategy, each selected strike corresponding to a selected outcome of the event, and each selected strike being selected from a plurality of strikes established for the auction, each of the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event, wherein the premium for the order is determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating each of the derivatives strategies in the order, the replication set including at least one replicating claim from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, one or more of the replicating claims in the auction sti-ilcing at one of the strikes.
In another additional embodiment, a method of hedging, includes the steps of determining an investment risk in one or more investments; and offsetting the investment risk by taking--a position in one or more derivatives strategies in a demand-based auction with an opposing risk, an order for the one or more derivatives strategies indicating one or more selected strikes and a payout profile for the derivatives strategy in the order, each selected strike corresponding to a selected outcome of the event, and each selected strike being selected from a .
plurality of strikes established for the auction, each of the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event, wherein the premium for the order is determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating each of the derivatives strategies in the order, the replication set including at least one replicating claim from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, one or more of each of the replicating claims in the auction striking at one of-the strikes.
In another additional embodiment, a method of speculating, includes the steps of determining an investment risk in at least one investment; and increasing the investment risk by taking a position in one or more derivatives strategies in a demand-based auction with a similar risk, an order for the one or more derivatives strategies. The order specifies one or more selected strikes: and a payout profile for the derivatives strategy, and can also specify a requested number of the derivatives strategy. Each selected strike corresponds to a selected outcome of the event, . each selected strike is selected from a plurality of strikes established for the auction, and each of the strikes corresponds to a possible outcome of the event. The premium for the order is determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating each of the _ 27 _ derivatives strategies in the order, the replication set including one or more replicating claims from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, one or more of the replicating claims in the auction striking at each one of the strikes.
In another additional embodiment, a computer program product capable of processing a S customer order including one or more derivatives strategies, in a demand-based auction including one or..more customer orders, the computer program product including a computer usable medium having computer readable program code embodied in the medium for causing a computer to: establish strikes for the auction, each one of the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; establish replicating claims for the auction, one or more of the replicating claims striking at one of the strikes; and replicate each derivatives strategy in the customer order .
with a replication set including at least one of the replicating claims in the auction; and determine a premium for the customer order by engaging in a demand-based valuation of each of the replicating claims in the replication set for each of the derivatives strategies in the customer order.
In another additional embodiment, an article of manufacture comprising an information storage medium encoded with a computer-readable data structure adapted for use in placing a customer order iri a demand-based auction over the Internet, the auction including at least one customer order, said data structure including: at least one data field with information identifying one or more selected strikes and a payout profile for each of the derivatives strategies in the customer order, each selected strike corresponding to a selected outcome of the event, and each selected strike being selected from a plurality of strikes established for the auction, each strike in , the auction corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; and one or more data fields with information identifying a premium for the order, the premium being determined as a result of a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating each of the derivatives strategies in the order, the replication set including at least one replicating claim from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, one or more of each of the replicating claims in the auction striking at one of the strikes.
In another additional embodiment, a derivatives strategy for a demand-based market, includes: a first designation of at least one selected strike for the derivatives strategy, each selected strike being selected from a plurality of strikes established for auction, each strike in the auction corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; a second designation of a payout profile for the derivatives strategy; and a price for the derivatives strategy, the price being _2g-determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating the first designation and the second designation of the derivatives strategy, the replication set including one or more replicating claims from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, one or more of the replicating claims in the auction striking at each strike in the auction.
In another additional embodiment, an investment vehicle for a demand-based auction, includes: a demand-based derivatives strategy providing investment capital to the auction, an amount of the provided investment capital being dependent upon a demand-based valuation of a replication set replicating the derivatives strategy, the replicating set including one or more of the replicating claims from a plurality of replicating claims established for the auction, one or more of the.replicating. claims in the auction striking at each one of the strikes in the auction.
In another additional embodiment, an article of manufacture comprising a propagated signal adapted for use in the performance of a method for trading a customer order including at least one of a derivatives strategy, in a demand-based auction including one or more customer orders, wherein the method includes the steps of.- establishing strikes for the auction, each one of 1 S the strikes corresponding to a possible outcome of the event; establishing replicating claims for the auction,-one or more of the replicating claims striking at one of the strikes; replicating each one of the derivatives strategies in the customer order with a replication set including one or more of the replicating claims in the auction; and determining a premium for the customer order by engaging in a demand-based valuation of each one of the replicating claims in the replication set for the derivatives strategy in the customer order; wherein the propagated signal is encoded with machine-readable information relating to the trade.
In another additional embodiment, a computer system for conducting demand-based auctions on an event, includes one or more user interface processors, a database unit, an auction.
processor and a calculation engine. The one or more interface processors are configured to communicate with a plurality of terminals which are adapted to enter demand-based order data for an auction. The database unit is configured to maintain an auction information database. The auction processor is configured to process at least one demand-based auction and to communicate with the user interface processor and the database unit, wherein the auction processor is configured to generate auction transaction data based on auction order data received from the user interface processor and to send the auction transaction data for storing to the database unit, and wherein the auction processor is further configured to establish a plurality of strikes for the auction, each strike corresponding to a possible outcome of the event, to establish a plurality of replicating claims for the auction, at least one replicating claim striking at a strike in the plurality of strikes, to replicate a contingent claim with a replication set including at least one of the plurality of replicating claims, and to send the replication set for storing to the database unit. The calculation engine is configured to determine at least one of an equilibrium price and a payout for the contingent claim as a function of a demand-based valuation of each of the replicating claims in the replication set stored in the database unit.
An object of the present invention is to provide systems and methods to support and facilitate a market structure for contingent claims related to observable events of economic significance, which includes one or more of the following advantages, in addition to those described above:
1. ready implementation and support using electronic computing and networking technologies;
2. reduction or elimination of the need to match bids to buy with offers to sell in order to create a market for derivatives;
3. reduction or eliminarion of the need for a derivatives intermediary to match bids and offers;
, 4. mathematical and.consistent calculation of returns based on demand for contingent claims;
S. increased liquidity and liquidity incentives;
6. statistical diversification of credit risk through the mutualization of multiple derivatives counterparties;
7. improved scalability by reducing the traditional linkage between the method of pricing for contingent claims and the quantity of the underlying claims available for investment;
8. increased price transparency;
9. improved efficiency of information aggregation mechanisms;
10. reduction of event risk, such as the risk of discontinuous market events such as crashes;
11. opportunities for binding offers of liquidity to the market;
12. reduced incentives for strategic behavior by traders;
13. increased market for contingent claims;
14. improved price discovery;
15. improved self consistency;
16. reduced influence by market makers;
17. ability to accommodate virtually unlimited demand;
18. ability to isolate risk exposures;
19. increased trading precision, transaction certainty and flexibility;
20. ability to create valuable new markets with a sustainable competitive advantage;
21. new source of fee revenue without putting capital at risk; and
22. increased capital efficiency.
A further object of the present invention is to provide systems and methods for the electronic exchange of contingent claims related to observable events of economic significance, which includes one or more of the following advantages:
1. reduced transaction costs, including settlement and clearing costs, associated with derivatives transactions and insurable claims;
2. reduced dependence on complicated valuation models for trading and risk management of derivatives;
3. reduced need for an exchange or market maker to manage market risk by hedging;
4. increased availability to traders of accurate and up-to-date information on the trading of contingent claims, including information regarding the aggregate amounts invested across all states of events of economic significance, and including over varying time periods;
5. reduced exposure of the exchange to credit risk;
6. increased availability of information on credit risk and market risk borne by traders of contingent claims;

7. increased availability of information on marginal returns from trades and investments that can be displayed instantaneously after the returns adjust during a trading period;
8. reduced need for a derivatives intermediary or exchange to match bids and offers;
9. increased ability to customize demand-based adjustable return (DBAR) payouts to permit replication of traditional financial products and their derivatives;
10. comparability of profit and loss scenarios to those expected by traders for purchases and sales of digital options and other derivatives, without conventional sellers;
11. increased data generation; and 12. reduced exposure of the exchange to market risk.
Other additional embodiments include features for an enhanced parimutuel wagering system and method, which are described in further detail in Chapter 15 below.
In one of such other additional embodiment, a method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering includes the steps of enabling at least two types of bets to be offered in the same or common betting pool;
and offering at least one of the two types of enabled bets to bettors. The different types of bets (e.g., trifecta bets, finish bet, show bets, as described in further detail in Chapter 15 below) can be processed in the same betting pool, for example, by configuring equivalent combinations of fundamental bets for each type of bet, and performing a demand-based valuation of each of the fundamental bets in the betting pool.
In another additional embodiment, a method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering, includes the steps of establishing a plurality of fundamental outcomes; receiving an indication of limit odds, a premium and a selected outcome; and determining the payout as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the premium and the total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes. Each fundamental outcome corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of an underlying event (e.g., a wagering event such as a lottery, a sporting event or a horse or dog race), and the selected outcome corresponds to one or more fundamental outcomes.
In another additional embodiment, a method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering includes the steps of-. establishing a plurality of fundamental outcomes in a betting pool; receiving an indication of limit odds, a premium, and a selected outcome; and determining final odds as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the premium and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fimdamental outcomes in the betting pool. Each fundamental outcome corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of an underlying event, and the selected outcome corresponds to one or more of the fundamental outcomes.
S In another additional embodiment, a method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering, includes the steps of establishing a plurality of fimdamental outcomes; receiving an indication of limit odds, a desired payout, and a selected outcome; and determining a premium as a fimction of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the desired payout and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fimdamental outcomes. Each fundamental outcome corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of an underlying event; and the selected outcome corresponds to one or more of the fimdamental outcomes.
In another additional embodiment, a method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering, includes the steps of establishing a plurality of fundamental outcomes in a betting pool; receiving an indication of limit odds, a desired payout, and a selected outcome; and 1 S determining final odds as a fimction of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the desired payout and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fizndamental outcomes in the betting pool. Each fundamental outcome corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of an underlying event, and the selected outcome corresponds to one or more of the fundamental outcomes.
In another additional embodiment, a method for processing a bet in an enhanced parimutuel betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool including one or more bets, includes the steps of establishing fundamental outcomes in a betting pool;
establishing fimdamental bets on each fimdamental outcome in the betting pool; configuring an equivalent combination of fimdamental bets for the~bet as a function of a selected outcome for the bet; and determining at least one of a premium and a payout for the wager as a function of a demand-based valuation of each fundamental bet in the equivalent combination for the wager. Each one of the fimdamental outcomes corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of the underlying event, and the selected outcome for the bet corresponds to one or more of the fimdamental outcomes.
In another additional embodiment, a method for processing a bet in an enhanced parimutuel betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool including one or more wagers, includes the steps of-. establishing fundamental outcomes in a betting pool;
establishing fundamental bets on each fundamental outcome in the betting pool; configuring an equivalent combination of fimdamental bets for the wager as a fimction of a selected outcome for the wager;
and determining a price for each fundamental bet as a fiuiction of a price of each of the other fundamental bets in the betting pool, a total filled amount in each fundamental outcome, and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes in the betting pool. Each one of the fundamental outcomes corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of the underlying event; and the selected outcome for the wager corresponds to one or more of the fundamental outcomes.
In another additional embodiment, a method for betting on an underlying event, includes the steps of providing an indication of limit odds, a requested premium, and a selected outcome, for a bet on a selected outcome of the underlying event; and receiving an indication of final odds for the bet. The selected outcome corresponds to one or more fimdamental outcomes in the betting pool, and each of the fimdamental outcomes corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of the underlying event. The final odds are determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of an equivalent combination of fizndamental bets. The equivalent combination includes one or more fi~ndamental bets. Each fimdamental.bet in the betting pool betting on a respective fundamental outcome. The equivalent combination of fimdamental bets are configured as a function of the selected outcome for the bet.
In another additional embodiment, a method for betting on an underlying event, includes the steps of providing an indication of limit odds, a desired payout, and a selected outcome, for a bet on a selected outcome of an underlying event; and receiving an indication of final odds for the bet. The selected outcome corresponds to one or more fundamental outcomes, each of the fimdamental outcomes in the betting pool corresponding to one or more possible outcomes of the underlying event. The final odds are determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of an equivalent combination of fundamental bets. The equivalent combination includes one or more of the fundamental bets, each fimdamental bet betting on a respective fundamental outcome. The equivalent combination is configured as a fiction of the selected outcome for the.bet.
In another additional embodiment, a vehicle for betting in an enhanced parimutuel betting pool, includes: a wager betting a filled premium amount on a selected outcome of an underlying event, the wager including an indication of limit odds on the selected outcome, and one of a requested premium and a desired payout on the selected outcome. The filled premium is determined as a function of the one of the requested premium and the desired payout and a comparison of the limit odds with final odds on the wager. The final odds are determined by -3.~-engaging in a demand-based valuation of each of the fimdamental bets in a combination of fimdamental bets equivalent to the wager. The combination includes one or more fundamental bets from the plurality of fundamental bets established for the betting pool.
Each fimdamental bet in the betting pool betting on a fundamental outcome of the underlying event. Each fi~ndamental outcome corresponds to one or mole of the possible outcomes of the underlying event. The selected outcome corresponds to one or more of the fimdamental outcomes. The combination of fundamental bets is configured as a fimction of the selected outcome of the wager.
Tn another additional embodiment, a computer system for conducting a betting pool on an ' . underlying event, includes one or more processors, that is configured to:
establish fundamental outcomes for the underlying event; establish fundamental bets for the .underlying.event; receive an indication of limit odds, one of a requested premium and a desired payout, and a selected outcome, for a wager on a selected outcome of the underlying event;.configure an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for the wager as a fimction of the selected outcome of the wager;'and determine final odds for the wager by engaging in a demand-based valuation of the fundamental bets in the equivalent combination. Each of the fundamental outcomes corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of the event. Each fundamental bet bets on a respective fimdamental outcome in the betting pool. The selected outcome corresponds to one or more of the fimdamental outcomes in the betting pool, and each fundamental outcome corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of the underlying event.
In another additional embodiment, a computer system, for placing a bet in a betting pool on an.underlying event, includes one or more processors configured to: provide an indication of limit odds, one of a desired payout and a requested premium, and a selected outcome, for a bet on a selected outcome of an underlying event; and receive an indication of final odds for the bet.
The selected outcome corresponds to one or more of a plurality of fimdamental outcomes in the betting pool, with each fundamental outcome corresponding to one or more possible outcomes of the underlying event. The final odds are determined by having the processors engage in a demand-based valuation of an equivalent combination of fimdamental bets for the bet. The equivalent combination includes one or more fimdamental bets, each of which bet on a respective fimdamental outcome. The equivalent combination i~ configured as a fimction of the selected outcome for the bet.

In another additional embodiment, a computer program product is capable of processing a wager in a betting pool including at least one wager. The computer program product includes a computer usable medium having computer readable program code embodied in the medium for causing a computer or a system to: establish fundamental outcomes for the underlying event;
establish fundamental bets for the underlying event; receive an indication of limit odds, one of a requested premium and a desired payout, and a selected outcome on the underlying event, for-a wager on the selected outcome; configure an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for the wager as a function of the selected outcome of the wager; and determine final odds for the wager by engaging in a demand-based valuation of the fundamental bets in the equivalent combination.
Each of the fundamental outcomes corresponds to one or more of the possible outcomes of the underlying event. Each fundamental bet bets on a respective fundamental outcome. Theselected outcome corresponds to one or more of a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to a possible outcome of.the underlying event.
In another additional embodiment, an article of manufacture includes: an information storage medium encoded with a computer-readable data structure adapted for placing a wager over the Internet in a betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool includes one or more wagers, said data structure comprising: one or more data fields with information identifying at least one selected outcome of an underlying event, limit odds, and one of a requested premium and a desired payout for the wager; and one or more data fields with information identifying final odds for the wager. The final odds are determined as a result of a demand-based valuation of fundamental bets in a combination of fundamental bets equivalent to the wager configured as a function of the selected outcome. The combination includes one or more of the fundamental bets established for the betting pool. Each fundamental bet bets on a fundamental outcome of the underlying event. Each fundamental outcome corresponds to at least one possible outcome of the event; and the selected outcome corresponds to one or more of the fundamental outcomes.
In another additional embodiment, an article of manufacture comprising a propagated signal adapted for use in the performance of a method for conducting a betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool includes one or more wagers. The signal is encoded with machine-readable information relating to the wager. The method includes the steps of establishing fundamental outcomes for the underlying event; establishing fundamental bets for the underlying event; receiving an indication of limit odds, a requested premium and/or a desired payout, and a selected outcome, for a wager on a selected outcome on the underlying event;

configuring an equivalent combination of fiuidamental bets for the wager as a fimction of the selected outcome of the wager; and determining final odds for the wager by engaging in a demand-based valuation of the fimdamental bets in the equivalent combination.
Each fimdamental outcome corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of the event.
Each fundamental bet bets on a respective fimdamental outcome. The selected outcome corresponds to one or more of a plurality of fimdamental outcomes. Each of the fimdamental outcomes corresponds to one or more of the possible outcomes of the event. Each fimdamental bet bets on .
a respective fimdamental outcome. The selected outcome corresponds to one or more of the plurality of fimdamental outcomes. Each fimdamental outcome corresponds to one or more possible outcomes of the underlying event.
Additional objects and advantages of the various embodiments of the invention are set .
forth in part in the description which follows, and in part are obvious- from the description; or may be learned by practice of the invention. The objects and advantages of the invention may also be realized 'and attained by means of the instrumentalities, systems, methods and.steps set .
1 S forth in the appended claims.
BRIEF DESCRIPTION OF THE DRAWINGS
The accompanying drawings, which are incorporated in and from a part of the specification, illustrate embodiments of the present invention and, together with the description;
serve to explain the principles of the invention.
FIG: 1 is a schematic view of various forms of telecommunications between DBAR
trader clients:and a.preferred embodiment of a DBAR contingent claims exchange implementing the present invention.
FIG. 2 is a schematic view of a central controller of a preferred embodiment of a DBAR
contingent claims exchange network architecture implementing the present invention.
FIG. 3 is a schematic depiction of the trading process on a preferred embodiment of a DBAR contingent claims exchange.
FIG. 4 depicts data storage devices of a preferred embodiment of a DBAR
contingent claims exchange.
FIG. 5 is a flow diagram illustrating the processes of a preferred embodiment of DBAR
contingent claims exchange in executing a DBAR range derivatives investment.
FIG. 6 is an illustrative HTML interface page of a preferred embodiment of a DBAR
contingent claims exchange.

FIG. ? is a schematic view of market data flow to a preferred embodiment of a DBAR
contingent claims exchange.
FIG. 8 is an illustrative graph of the implied liquidity effects for a group of DBAR
contingent claims.
FIG. 9a is a schematic representation of a traditional interest rate swap transaction.
FIG. 9b is a schematic of investor relationships for an illustrative group of DBAR
contingent claims.
FIG. 9c shows a tabulation of credit ratings and margin trades for each investor in to an illustrative group of DBAR contingent claims.
FIG. l0.is a schematic view of a feedback process for a preferred embodiment of DBAR
contingent claims exchange.
FIG. 11' depicts illustrative DBAR data structures for use in a preferred embodiment of a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 12. depicts a preferred embodiment of a method for processing limit and market orders in a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 13 depicts a preferred embodiment of a method for calculating a multistate composite equilibrium in a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 14 depicts a preferred embodiment of a method for calculating a multistate profile equilibrium in a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 15 depicts a preferred embodiment of a method for converting "sale"
orders to buy orders in a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 16: depicts a preferred embodiment of a method for adjusting implied probabilities for demand-based adjustable return contingent.claims to account for transaction or exchange fees in a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 1? depicts a preferred embodiment of a method for filling and removing lots of limit orders in a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 18 depicts a preferred embodiment of a method of payout distribution and fee collection in a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.

FIG. 19 depicts illustrative DBAR data structures used in another embodiment of a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 20 depicts another embodiment of a method for processing limit and market orders in another embodiment of a Demand-Based Adjustable Return Digital Options Exchange of the present invention.
FIG. 21 depicts an upward shift in the earnings expectations curve which can be protected by trading digital options and other contingent claims on earnings in successive quarters according to the embodiments of the present invention.
FIG. 22 depicts a network implementation of a demand-based market or auction . according to the embodiments of the present invention.
FIG. 23 depicts cash flows for each participant trading a principle-protected ECI-linked FRN.
FIG. 24 depicts an example time line for a demand-based market trading DBAR-enabled ~FRNs or swaps according: to the embodiments of the present invention.
FIG. 25 depicts an example of an embodiment of a demand-based market or auction with digital options and DBAR-enabled products.
FIG. 26 depicts an example of an embodiment of a demand-based market or auction with replicated derivatives strategies, digital options and other DBAR-enabled products and derivatives.
FIGS. 27A, 27B and 27C depict an example of an embodiment replicating a vanilla call for a demand-based market or auction with a strike of -325.
FIGS. 28A, 28B and 28C depict an example of an embodiment replicating a call spread for a demand-based market or auction with strikes -375 and -225.
FIG. 29 depicts an example of an embodiment of.a demand-based market or auction with = derivatives strategies, structured instruments and other products that are DBAR-enabled by replicating them into a vanilla replicating basis.
FIG. 30 illustrates the components of a digital replicating basis for an example embodiment in which derivatives strategies are DBAR-enabled by replicating them into the digital replicating basis.

FIG. 31 illustrates the components of the vanilla replicating basis referenced in FIG. 29.
FIG. 32 to 68 illustrates a DBAR System Architecture that implements the example embodiment depicted in Figures 29 and 31.
DETAILED DESCRIPTION OF PREFERRED EMBODIMENTS
This Detailed Description of Preferred Embodiments is organized into sixteen sections.
The first section provides an overview of systems and methods for trading or investing in groups of DBAR contingent claims. The second section describes in detail some of the important features of systems and methods for trading or investing in groups of DBAR
contingent claims.
The third section of this Detailed Description of Preferred Embodiments provides detailed descriptions of two preferred embodiments of the present invention:
investments in a group of DBAR contingent claims, and investments in a portfolio of groups of such claims. The fourth section discusses methods for calculating risks attendant on investments in groups and portfolios of groups of DBAR contingent claims. .The fifth section of this Detailed Description addresses liquidity and price/quantity relationships in preferred embodiments of systems and methods of 1 S the present invention. The sixth section provides a detailed description of a DBAR Digital Options Exchange. The seventh section provides a detailed description of another embodiment of a DBAR Digital Options Exchange. The eighth section presents a network implementation of this DBAR Digital Options Exchange. The ninth section presents a structured instrument implementation of a demand-based market or auction. The tenth section presents systems and methods for replicating derivatives strategies using contingent claims such as digitals or digital options, and trading such replicated derivatives strategies in a demand-based market. The eleventh section presents systems and methods for replicating derivatives strategies and other contingent claims (e.g., structured instruments), into a vanilla replicating basis (a basis including vanilla replicating claims, and sometimes also digital replicating claims), and trading such replicated derivatives strategies in a demand-based market or auction, pricing such derivatives strategies in the vanilla replicating basis. The twelfth section presents a detailed description of FIGS. 1 to 28 accompanying this specification. The thirteenth section presents a description of the DBAR system architecture, including additional detailed descriptions of figures accompanying the specification, with particular detail directed to the embodiments described in the eleventh section, and as illustrated in FIGS. 32 to 68. The fourteenth section of the Detailed Description discusses some of the salient advantages of the methods and systems of the present invention. The fifteenth section presents enhanced parimutuel wagering systems and methods.
0_ The sixteenth section is a Technical Appendix providing additional information on the multistate allocation method of the present invention.
The last section is a conclusion of the Detailed Description. More ecifically, this Detailed Description of the Preferred sp Embodiments is organized as follows:

1 Overview: Exchanges and Markets for DBAR Contingent Claims 1.1 Exchange Design 1.2 Market Operation 1.3 Network Implementation 2 Features of DBAR
Contingent Claims 2.1 DBAR Contingent Claim Notation 2.2 Units of Investment and Payouts 2.3 Canonical Demand Reallocation Functions 2.4 Computing Investment Amounts to Achieve Desired Payouts 2.5 A Canonical DRF Example 2.6 Interest Considerations 2.7 Returns and Probabilities 2.8 Computations When Invested Amounts are Large 3 Examples of Groups of DBAR Contingent Claims 3.1 DBAR Range Derivatives 3.2 DBAR Portfolios 4 Risk C alculations in Groups of DBAR Contingent Claims 4.1 Market Risk , 4.1.1 Capital-At-Risk Determinations 4.1.2 Capital-At-Risk Determinations Using Monte Carlo Simulation Techniques 4.1. 3 Capital-At-Risk Determinations Using Historical Simulation Techniques 4.2 Credit Risk 4.2.1 Credit-Capital-At-Risk Determinations 4.2.2 Credit-Capital-At-Risk Determinations using Monte Carlo Simulation Techniques 4.2.3 Credit-Capital-At-Risk Historical Simulation Techniques _41 _ S Liquidity and Price/Quantity Relationships 6 DBAR Digital Options Exchange 6.1 Representation of Digital Options as DBAR
Contingent Claims 6.2 Construction of Digital Options Using DBAR
Methods and Systems 6.3 Digital Option Spreads 6.4 Digital Option Strips 6.5 Multistate Allocation Algorithm for Replicating "Sell" Trades 6.6 Clearing and Settlement 6.7 Contract Initialization 6.8 Conditional Investments, or Limit Orders 6.9 Sensitivity Analysis and Depth of Limit Order Book 6.10 Networking of DBAR Digital Options Exchanges 7 DBAR DOE:
Another Embodiment 7.1 Special Notation 7.2 Elements of Example DBAR DOE Embodiment 7.3 Mathematical Principles 7.4 Equilibrium Algorithm 7.5 Sell Orders 7.6 Arbitrary Payout Options 7.7 Limit Order Book Optimization 7.8 Transaction Fees 7.9 An Embodiment of the Algorithm to Solve the Limit Order.

BookOptimization 7.10 Limit Order Book Display 7.11 Unique Price Equilibrium Proof 8 Network Implementation 9 Struct ured Instrument Trading 9.1 Overview: Customer Oriented DBAR-enabled Products 9.2 Overview: FRNs and swaps 9.3 Parameters: FRNs and swaps vs. digital options 9.4 Mechanics: DBAR-enabling FRNs and swaps 9.5 Example: Mapping FRNs into Digital Option Space 9.6 Conclusion Replicating Derivatives Strategies Using Digital Options 10.1 The General Approach to Replicating Derivatives Strategies With Digital 5 Options 10.2 Application of General Results to Special Cases 10.3 Estimating the Distribution of the Underlying U

10.4 Replication P&L for a Set of Orders Appendix 10A: Notation Used in Section 10 10 Appendix l OB: The General Replication Theorem Appendix IOC: Derivations from Section 10.3 11 Replicating and Pricing Derivatives Strategies using Vanilla Options 11.1 Replicating Derivatives Strategies Using Digital Options 11.2 Replicating Claims Using a Vanilla Replicating Basis 11.3 Extensions to the General Replication Theorem 11.4 Mathematical Restrictions for the Equilibrium 11.5 Examples of DBAR Equilibria with the Digital Replicating Basis and the Vanilla Replicating Basis Appendix 11A: Proof of General Replication Theorem in Section 11.2.3 Appendix 11B: Derivatives of the Self Hedging Theorem of Section 11.4.5 Appendix 11C: Probability Weighted Statistics from Sections 11.5.2 and 11.5.3 Appendix 11D: Notation Used in the Body of Text 12 Detailed Description of the Drawings in Figs. 1 to 28 13 DBAR System Architecture (and Description of the Drawings in Figs. 32 to 68) 13.1 Terminology and Notation 13.2 Overview 13.3 Application Architecture 13.4 Data 13.5 Auction and Event Configuration 13.6 Order Processing 13.7 Auction State 13.8 Startup 13.9 CE (calculation engine) implementation 13.10 LE (limit order book engine) implementation 13.11 Network Architecture 13.12 Figures 32 - 68 Legend S Appendix 13A: Descriptions of Element Names in DBAR System Architecture 14 Advantages of Preferred Embodiments 1 S Enhanced Parimutuel Wagering 1 S.1 Background and Summary of Example Emobidments 15.2 Details and Mathematics of Enhanced Parimutuel Wagering 15.3 Horse-Racing Example .
15.4 Additional Examples of Enhanced Parimutuel Wagering Appendix 15: Notation Used in Section 15 16 Technical Appendix 17 Conclusion In this specification, including the description of preferred or example embodiments of the present invention, specific terminology will be used for the sake of clarity. However, the invention is not.intended to be limited to the specific terms so used, and it is to be understood that each specific term includes all equivalents.
' 1. OVERVIEW: EXCHANGES AND MARI~TS FOR DBAR CONTINGENT1.1 Exchange Design This section describes preferred methods for structuring DBAR contingent claims and for designing exchanges for the trading of such claims. The design of the exchange is important for effective contingent claims investment in accordance with the present invention. Preferred embodiments of such systems include processes for establishing defined states and allocating returns, as described below.
(a) Establishing Defined States and Strikes: In preferred embodiments, a distribution of possible outcomes for an observable event is partitioned into defined ranges or states, and strikes can be established corresponding to measurable outcomes which occur at one of an upper and/or a lower end of each defined range or state.
In certain preferred embodiments, one state always occurs because the states are mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive. Traders in such an embodiment invest on their expectation of a return resulting from the occurrence of a particular outcome within a selected state. Such investments allow traders to hedge the possible outcomes of real-world events of economic significance represented by S the states. In preferred embodiments of a group of DBAR contingent claims, unsuccessful trades or investments finance the successful trades or investments.
In such embodiments the states for a given contingent claim preferably are defined in such a way that the states are mutually exclusive and form the basis of a probability distribution, namely, the sum of the probabilities of all the uncertain outcomes is unity. For example, states corresponding to stock price closing values can be established to support a group of DBAR contingent claims by partitioning the distribution of possible closing values for the stock on a given future date into .
ranges. The distribution of future stock prices, discredzed in this way into defined states, forms a probability distribution in the sense that each state is mutually exclusive, and the sum of the probabilities:of the stock closing within each defined state or between two strikes surrounding the defined state, at the given date is unity.
In preferred embodiments, traders can simultaneously invest in selected multiple states or strikes within a given distribution, without immediately breaking up their investment to fit into each defined states or strikes selected for investment. Traders thus may place mufti-state or mufti-strike investments in order to replicate a desired distribution of returns from a group of contingent claims. This may be accomplished in a preferred embodiment of a DBAR
exchange through the use of suspense accounts in which mufti-state or mufti-strike investments are tracked and reallocated periodically as returns adjust in response to amounts invested during a trading period. At the end of a given trading period, a mufti-state or mufti-strike investment may be reallocated to achieve the desired distribution of payouts based upon the final invested amounts across the distribution of states or strikes. Thus, in such a preferred embodiment, the invested amount allocated to each of the selected states or strikes, and the corresponding respective returns, are finalized only at the closing of the trading period. An example of a mufti-state investment illustrating the use of such a suspense account is provided in Example 3.1.2, below. Other examples of multi-state investments are provided in Section 6, below, which describes embodiments of the present invention that implement DBAR Digital Options Exchanges. Other examples of investments in derivatives strategies with multiple strikes are shown and discussed below, including, inter alia, in Sections 10 and 11.
(b) Allocating Returns: In a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR
contingent claims according to the present invention, returns for each state are specified. In such an embodiment, while the amount invested for a given trade may be fixed, the return is adjustable. Determination of the returns for a particular state can be a simple fimction of the.amount invested in that state and the total amount invested for all of the defined states for a group of contingent claims. However, alternate preferred embodiments can also accommodate methods of return determination that include other factors in addition to the invested amounts. For example, in a group of DBAR contingent claims where unsuccessful investments fund returns to successful investments, the returns can be allocated based on the relative amounts invested in each state and also on properties of the outcome, such as the magnitude of the price changes in underlying securities. An example in section 3.2 below illustrates such an embodiment in the context of a securities portfolio (c) Determining Investment Amounts: In other embodiments, a group of DBAR
contingent claims can be modeled as digital options, providing a predetermined or defined payout if they expire in-the-money, and providing no payout if they expire out-of the-money. In this embodiment, the investor or trader specifies a requested payout for a DBAR digital option, and selects the outcomes for which the digital option will expire "in the money," and can specify a limit on the amount they wish to invest in such a digital option. Since the payout amount per digital option (or per an order for a digital option) is predetermined or defined, investment amounts for each digital option are determined at the end of the trading period along with the allocation of payouts per digital option as a function of the requested payouts, selected outcomes (and limits on investment amounts, if any) for each of the digital options ordered during the trading period, and the total amount invested in the auction or market. This embodiment is described in Section 7 below, along with another embodiment of demand-based markets or auctions for digital options described in Section 6 below. In additional embodiments, a variety of contingent claims, including derivatives strategies and financial products and structured.
instruments can be replicated or approximated with a set of DBAR contingent claims (sometimes called, "replicating claims,") otherwise regarded as mapping the contingent claims into a DBAR contingent claim space or basis. The DBAR
contingent claims or replicating claims, can include replicating digital options or, in a vanilla replicating basis, include replicating vanilla options alone, or together with replicating digital options. The price of such replicated contingent claims is determined by engaging in the demand-based or DBAR valuation of each of the replicating digital options and/or vanilla options in the replication set.
These embodiments are described in Sections 10 and 1 l, as well as a system architecture described in Section 13 to accomplish a technical implementation of the entire process.
1.2 Market Operation (a) Termination Criteria: In a preferred embodiment of a method of the present invention, returns to investments in the plurality of defined states are allocated (and in another embodiment for DBAR digital options, investment amounts are determined) after the fulfillment of one or more predetermined termination criteria. In preferred embodiments, these criteria include the expiration of.a - "trading period" and the determination of the outcome of the relevant event after an "observation period." In the trading period, traders invest on their expectation of a return resulting from the occurrence of a particular outcome within a selected defined state, such as the state that IBM stock will close between 120 and 125 on July 6, 1999. In a preferred embodiment, the duration of the trading period is known to all participants; returns associated with each state vary during the trading period with changes in invested amounts; and returns are allocated based on the total amount invested in all states relative to the amounts invested in each of the states as at the end of the trading period.
Alternatively, the duration of the trading period can be unlrnown to the participants. The trading period can end, for example, at a randomly selected time. Additionally, the trading period could end depending upon the occurrence of some event associated or related to the event of economic significance, or upon the fulfillment of some criterion. For example, for DBAR contingent claims traded on reinsurance risk (discussed in Section 3 below), the trading period could close after an nth catastrophic natural event (e.g., a fourth hurncane), or after a catastrophic event of a certain magnitude (e.g., an earthquake of a magnihtde of S 5.5 or higher on the Richter scale). The trading period could also close after a certain volume, amount, or frequency of trading is reached in a respective auction or market.
The observation period can be provided as a time period during which the contingent events are observed and the relevant outcomes determined for the purpose of allocating returns. In a preferred embodiment, no trading occurs during the observation period.
The expiration date, or "expiration," of a group of DBAR contingent claims as used in this specification occurs when the termination criteria are fulfilled for that group of DBAR contingent claims. In a preferred embodiment, 1 S the expiration is the date, on or after the occurrence of the relevant event, when the outcome is ascertained or observed. This expiration is similar to well-known expiration features in traditional options or futures in which a future date, i.e., the expiration date, is specified as the date upon which the value of the option or future will be determined by reference to the value of the underlying financial product on the expiration date.
The duration of a contingent claim as defined for purposes of this specification is simply the amount of time remaining until expiration from any given reference date. A trading start date ("TSD") and a trading end date ("TED"), as used in the specification, refer to the beginning and end of a time period ("trading period") during which traders can make investments in a group of DBAR contingent claims. Thus, the time during which a group of DBAR
contingent claims is open for investment or trading ; i.e., the difference between the TSD and TED, may be referred to as the trading period. In preferred embodiments, there can be one or many trading periods for a given expiration date, opening successively through time. For example, one trading period's TED
may coincide exactly with the subsequent trading period's TSD, or in other examples, trading periods may overlap.
_~g_ The relationship between the duration of a contingent claim, the number of trading periods employed for a given event, and the length and timing of the trading periods, can be arranged in a variety of ways to maximize trading or achieve other goals. In preferred embodiments at least one trading period occurs -- that is, starts and ends -- prior in time to the identification of the outcome of the relevant event. In other words, in preferred embodiments, the trading period will most likely temporally precede the event defining the claim. This need not always be. so, since the outcome of an event may not be known for some time thereby enabling trading periods to end (or even start) subsequent to the occurrence of the event, but before its outcome is known.
A nearly continuous or "quasi-continuous" market can be made available by creating multiple trading periods for the same event, each having its own closing returns. Traders can make investtrients during successive trading periods as the returns change. In this way, profits-and-losses can be realized at least as frequently as in current derivatives markets. This is how derivatives traders currently are able to hedge options, futures, and other derivatives trades. In preferred embodiments of the present invention, traders may be able to realize profits and at varying frequencies, including more frequently than daily.
(b) Market Efficiency and Fairness: Market prices reflect, among other things, the distribution of information available to segments of the participants transacting in the market. In most markets, some participants will be better informed than others. In house-banking or traditional markets, market makers protect themselves from more informed counterparties by increasing their bid-offer spreads.
In preferred embodiments of DBAR contingent claim markets, there may be no market makers as such who need to protect themselves. It may nevertheless be necessary to put in place methods of operation in such markets in order to prevent manipulation of the outcomes underlying groups of DBAR contingent claams or the returns payable for various outcomes. One such mechanism is to introduce an element of randomness as to the time at:which a trading period closes. Another mechanism to minimize the likelihood and effects of market manipulation is to introduce an element of randomness to the duration of the observation period. For example, a DBAR contingent claim might settle against an average of market closing prices during a time interval that is partially:
randomly determined, as opposed to a market closing price on a specific day.
Additionally, in preferred embodiments incentives can be employed in S order to induce traders to invest earlier in a trading period rather than later. For example, a DRF may be used which allocates slightly higher returns to earlier investments in a successful state than later investments in that state. For DBAR
digital options, an OPF may be used which determines slightly lower (discounted) prices for earlier investments than later investments. Earlier investments may be valuable in preferred embodiments since they work to enhance liquidity and promote more uniformly meaningful price information during the trading period.
(c) Credit Risk: In preferred embodiments of a DBAR. contingent claims market, the dealer or exchange is substantially protected from primary market risk by the fimdamental principle underlying the operation of the system -- that returns to - successful investments are fiuided by losses from unsuccessful investments.
The credit risk in such preferred embodiments is distributed among all the market participants. If, for example, leveraged investments are permitted within a group of DBAR contingent claims, it may not be possible to collect the leveraged unsuccessful investments in order to distribute these amounts among the successful investments.
In almost all such cases there exists, for any given trader within a group of DBAR-contingent claims, a non-zero possibility of default, or credit risk.
Such credit risk is, of course, ubiquitous to all financial transactions facilitated with credit.
One way to address this risk is to not allow leveraged investments within the. group of DBAR contingent claims, which is a preferred embodiment of the system and methods of the present invention. In other preferred embodiments, traders in a DBAR exchange may be allowed to use limited leverage, subject to real-time margin monitoring, including calculation of a trader's impact on the overall level of credit risk in the DBAR system and the particular group of contingent claims. These risk management calculations should be significantly more tractable and transparent than the types of analyses credit risk managers typically perform in conventional derivatives markets in order to monitor counterparty credit risk.
An important feature of preferred embodiments of the present invention is the ability to provide diversification of credit risk among all the traders who invest in a group of DBAR contingent claims. In such embodiments, traders make investments (in the units of value as defined for the group) in a common distribution of states in the expectation of receiving a return if a given state is determined to have occurred. In preferred embodiments, all traders, through their investments in defined states for a group of contingent claims, place these invested amounts with a central exchange or intermediary which, for each trading period, pays the returns to successful investments from the losses on unsuccessful investments. In such embodiments, a given trader has all the other traders in the eXChange as counterparties, effecting a mutualization of counterparties and counterparty credit risk exposure. Each trader therefore assumes credit risk to a portfolio of counterparties rather than to a single counterparty.
Preferred embodiments of the DBAR contingent claim and exchange of the present invention present four principal advantages in managing the credit risk inherent in leveraged transactions. First, a preferred form of DBAR contingent claim entails limited liability investing. Investment liability is limited in these embodiments in the sense that the maximum amount a trader can lose is the amount invested. In this respect, the limited liability feature is similar to that of a long option position in the traditional markets. By contrast, a short option position in traditional markets represents a potentially unlimited liability investment since the downside exposure can readily exceed the option premium and is, in theory, unbounded. Importantly, a group of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention can easily replicate returns of a traditional short option position while maintaining limited liability. 'The limited liability feature of a group of DBAR contingent claims is a direct consequence of the demand-side nature of the market. More specifically, in preferred embodiments there are no sales or short positions as there are in the traditional markets, even though traders in a group of DBAR contingent claims may be able to attain the return profiles of traditional short positions.

Second, in preferred embodiments, a trader within a group of DBAR J
contingent claims should have a portfolio of counterparties as described above.
As a consequence, there should be a statistical diversification of the credit risk such that the amount of credit risk borne by any one trader is, on average (and in all but exceptionally rare cases), less than if there were an exposure to a single counterparty as is frequently the case in traditional markets. In other words, in preferred embodiments of the system and methods of the present invention, each trader is able to take advantage of the diversification effect that is well known in portfolio analysis.
Third, in preferred embodiments of the present invention, the entire.
distribution of margin loans, and the aggregate amount of leverage and credit risk existing for a group of DBAR contingent claims, can be readily calculated and displayed to traders at any time before the fulfillment of all of the termination criteria for the group of claims. Thus, traders themselves may have access to 1 S important information regarding credit risk. In traditional markets such information is not readily available.
Fourth, preferred embodiments of a DBAR contingent claim exchange provide more information about the distribution of possible outcomes than do traditional market exchanges. Thus, as a byproduct of DBAR contingent claim trading according to preferred embodiments, traders have more information about the distribution of future possible outcomes for real-world events, which they can use to manage risk more effectively. For many traders, a significant part of credit risk is likely to be caused by market risk. Thus, in preferred embodiments of the present invention, the ability through an exchange or otherwise to control or at least provide information about market risk should have positive feedback effects for the management of credit risk.
A simple example of a group of DBAR contingent claims with the following assumptions, illustrates some of these features. The example uses the following basic assumptions:
~ two defined states (with predetermined termination criteria): (i) stock price appreciates in one month; (ii) stock price depreciates in one month; and ~ $lld0 has been invested in the appreciate state, and $q5 in the depreciate state.

If a trader then invests $1 in the appreciate state, if the stock in fact appreciates in the rrionth, then the trader will be allocated a payout of $1.9406 (=196/101) -- a return of $.9406 plus the original $1 investment (ignoring, for the purpose of simplicity in this illustration, a transaction fee). If, before the close of the trading period the trader desires effectively to "sell"
his investment in the appreciate state, he has two choices. He could sell the investment to a third party, which would necessitate crossing of a bid and an offer in a two-way order crossing network: Or; in a preferred embodiment of the method of the present invention, the trader can invest in the depreciate state, in proportion to the amount that had been invested in that state not counting the trader's "new" investments. In this example, in order to fully hedge his investment in the.appreciate state, the trader can invest $.95 (95/100) in the depreciate state. Under either possible outcome, therefore, the trader will receive a payout of $1.95, i.e., if the stock appreciates .
the trader will receive 196:95/101 = $1.95 and if the stock depreciates the trader will receive .
(196.95/95.95)*.95= $1.95.
1:3 Network Implementation 1 S A market or exchange for groups of DBAR contingent claims market according to the - invention is not designed to establish a counterparty-driven or order-matched market. Buyers' bids and sellers' offers do not need to be "crossed." As a consequence of the absence of a need for aworder crossing network, preferred embodiments of the present invention are particularly amenable to large-scale electronic network implementation on a wide area network or a private network (with, e:g., dedicated circuits) or the public Internet, for example.
Additionally, a network.implementation of the embodiments in which contingent claims are mapped or replicated into a vanilla replicating basis, in order to be subject to a demand-based or DBAR
valuation, is described in more detail in Section 13 below.
Preferred embodiments of an electronic network-based embodiment of the method of trading in accordance with the invention include one or more of the following features.
(a) User Accounts: DBAR contingent claims investment accounts are established using electronic methods.
(b) Interest and Margin Accounts: Trader accounts are maintained using electronic methods to record interest paid to traders on open DBAR contingent claim balances and to debit trader balances for margin loan interest. Interest is typically paid on outstanding investment balances for a group of DBAR contingent claims until the fulfillment of the termination criteria. Interest is typically charged on outstanding margin loans while such loans are outstanding. For some contingent claims, trade balance interest can be imputed into the closing returns of a trading period.
(c) Suspense Accounts: These accounts relate specifically to investments which have been made by traders, during trading periods, simultaneously in multiple states for the same event. Mufti-state trades are those in which amounts are invested over a range of states so that, if any of the states occurs, a return is allocated to the trader based on the closing return for the state which in fact occurred. DBAR digital options of the present invention, described in Section 6, provide other examples of ' mufti-state trades.
A trader can, of course, simply break-up or divide the mufti-state investment into many separate, single-state investments, although this approach might require the trader to keep rebalancing his portfolio of single state investments as returns adjust throughout the trading period as amounts invested in each state change.
Mufti-state trades can be used in order to replicate any arbitrary distribution of payouts that a trader may desire. For example, a trader might want to invest in all states in excess of a given value or price for a security underlying a contingent claim, e.g., the occurrence that a given stock price exceeds 100 at some future date. 'The trader might also want to receive an identical payout no matter what state occurs among those states. For a group of DBAR contingent claims there may well be many states for outcomes in which the stock price exceeds (e.g., greater than 100 and less than or equal to 101; greater than 101 and less than or equal to 102, etc.). In order to replicate a mufti-state investment using single state investments, a trader would need continually to rebalance the portfolio of single-state investments so that the amount invested in the selected mufti-states is divided among the states in proportion to the existing amount invested in those states. Suspense accounts can be employed so that the exchange, rather than the trader, is responsible for rebalancing the portfolio of single-state investments so that, at the end of the trading period, the amount of the mufti-state investment is allocated among the constituent states in such a way so as to replicate the trader's _5a_ desired distribution of payouts. Example 3.1.2 below illustrates the use of suspense accounts for mufti-state investments.
(d) Authentication: Each trader may have an account that may be authenticated using authenticating data.
(e) Data Security: The security of contingent claims transactions over the network may be ensured, using for example strong forms of public and private key encryption.
(f) Real-Time Market Data Server: Real-time market data may be provided to support frequent calculation of returns and to ascertain the outcomes during the observation.periods.
(g) Real-Time Calculation Engine Server: Frequent calculation of market returns may increase the efficient functioning of the market. Data on coupons, dividends, market interest rates, spot prices, and other market data can be used to calculate opening returns at the beginning of a trading period and to ascertain observable events during the observation period. Sophisticated simulation methods may be required for some groups of DBAR contingent claims in order to estimate expected returns, at least at the start of a trading period.
(h) Real-Time Risk Management Server: In order to compute trader margin requirements, expected returns fdr each trader should be computed frequently.
Calculations of "value-at-risk" in traditional markets can involve onerous matrix calculations and Monte Carlo simulations. Risk calculations in preferred embodiments of the present invention are simpler, due to the existence of information on the expected returns for each state. Such information is typically unavailable in traditional capital and reinsurance markets.
(i) Market Data Storage: A DBAR contingent claims exchange in accordance with the invention may generate valuable data as a byproduct of its operation.
These data are not readily available in traditional capital or insurance markets. In a preferred embodiment of the present invention, investments may be solicited over ranges of outcomes for market events, such as the event that the 30-year U.S.
' Treasury bond will close on a given date with a yield between 6:10% and 6.20%.
Investment in the entire distribution of states generates data that reflect the expectations of traders over the entire distribution of possible outcomes. The _5 network implementation disclosed in this specification may be used to capture, store and retrieve these data.
(j) Market Evaluation Server: Preferred embodiments of the method of the present invention include the ability to improve the market's e~ciency on an ongoing basis. This may readily be accomplished, for example, by comparing the predicted returns on a group of DBAR contingent claims returns with actual realized outcomes. If investors have rational expectations, then DBAR
contingent claim returns will, on average, reflect trader expectations, and these expectations will themselves be realized on average. In. preferred embodiments, efficiency measurements are made on defined states and investments over the entire distribution of possible outcomes, which can then be. used for statistical time series analysis with realized outcomes. The network implementation of the present invention may therefore include analytic servers to perform these analyses for the purpose of continually improving the efficiency of the market.
2. FEATURES OF DBAR CONTINGENT CLAIMS
In a preferred embodiment, a group of a DBAR contingent claims related to an observable event includes one or more of the following features:
(1) A defined set of collectively exhaustive states representing_possible real world outcomes related to an observable event. In preferred embodiments, the events are events of economic significance. The possible outcomes can typically be units of measurement associated with the event, e.g., an event of economic interest can be the closing index level of the S&P 500 one month in the future, and the possible outcomes can be entire range of index levels that are possible in one month. In a preferred embodiment, the states are defined to correspond to one or more of the possible outcomes over the entire range of possible outcomes, so that defined states for an event form a countable and discrete number of ranges of possible outcomes, and are collectively exhaustive in the sense of spanning the entire range of possible outcomes. For example, in a preferred embodiment, possible outcomes for the S&P 500 can range from greater than 0 to infinity (theoretically), and a defined state could be those index values greater than and less than or equal to 1100. In such preferred embodiments, exactly one state occurs when the outcome of the relevant event becomes known.
-S~-(2) The ability for traders to place trades on the designated states during one or more tradin~periods for each event. In a preferred embodiment, a DBAR contingent claim group defines the acceptable units of trade or value for the respective claim.
Such units may be dollars, barrels of oil, number of shares of stock, or any other unit or combination of units accepted by traders and the exchange for value.
(3) An accepted determination of the. outcorne.of the event for determinin which state or states have occurred. In a preferred embodiment, a group of DBAR
contingent claims defines the means by which the outcome of the relevant events is determined. For example, the level that the S&P 500 Index actually closed on a predetermined date would be an outcome observation which would enable the determination of the occurrence of one of the defined' states. A closing value of ..
1050 on that date, for instance, would allow the determination that the state between 1000 and 1100 occurred. : .
(4) The specification of a DRF which takes the traded amount for each trader for each state across the distribution of states as thaf distribution exists at the end of each trading period and calculates payouts .for each investments in each state conditioned upon the occurrence of each state. 1n preferred embodiments, this is done so that the total amount of payouts does not exceed the total amount invested by all the traders in all the states. The DRF can be used to show payouts should each state occur during the trading period, thereby providing to traders information as to the collective level of interest of all traders in each state.
(5) For DBAR di 'tal options, the specification of an OPF which takes the requested payout and selection of outcomes and limits on investment amounts (if any) per digital option at the end of each trading period and calculates the investment amounts per di '1g tal option, along with the payouts for each di 'tal option in each state conditioned upon the occurrence of each state. In this other embodiment, this is done by solving a nonlinear optimization problem which uses the DRF
along with a series of other parameters to determine an optimal investment amount per digital option while maximizing the possible payout per digital option.
(6) Payouts to traders for successful investments based on the total amount of the unsuccessful investments after deduction of the transaction fee and after fulfillment of the termination criteria.

(7) For DBAR digital options, investment amounts per di '1g tal option after factoring the transaction fee and after fulfillment of the termination criteria.
The states corresponding to the range of possible event outcomes are referred to as the "distribution" or "distribution of states." Each DBAR contingent claim group or "contract" is typically associated with one distribution of states. The distribution will typically be defined for events of economic interest for investment by traders having the expectation of a return for a reduction of risk ("hedging"), or for an increase of risk ("speculation"). For example, the . distribution can be based upon the values of stocks, bonds, futures, and foreign exchange rates. It can also be based upon the values of commodity indices, economic statistics (e.g., consumer price inflation monthly reports), property-casualty losses; weather patterns for a certain geographical region, and any other measurable or observable occurrence or any other event in which traders would not be economically indifferent even in the absence of a trade on the outcome of the event.
2.1 DBAR Claim Notation The following notation is used in this specification to facilitate fiuther description of DBAR contingent claims:
m represents the number of traders for a given group of DBAR contingent claims n represents the number of states for a given distribution associated with a given group of DBAR contingent claims A represents a matrix with m rows and n columns, where the element at the i-th row and j-th column, a;,~, is the amount that trader i has invested in state j in the expectation of a return should state j occur . Tj represents a matrix with n rows and n columns where element ~;~ is the payout per unit of investment in state i should state j occur ("unit payouts") R represents a matrix with n rows and n columns where element r;~ is the return per unit of investment in state i should state j occur, i.e., r,~= ~;~-1 ("unit returns") P represents a matrix with m rows and n columns, where the element at the i-th row and j-th column, p;,~, is the payout to be made to trader i should state j occur, i.e., P
is equal to the matrix product A~~.
-S~-P~~, represents the j-th column of P, for j=l ..n, which contains the payouts to each investment should state j occur P;,~ represents the i-th row of P, for i=1 ..m, which contains the payouts to trader i s; where i = l ..n, represents a state representing a range of possible outcomes of an observable event.
T; where i = l ..n, represents the total amount traded in the expectation of the occurrence of state i T represents the total traded amount over the entire distribution of states, i.e.
T = ~T,.
i=l..n - f(A,X) represents the exchange's transaction fee, which can depend on the entire distribution of traded amounts placed across all the states as well as other factors, X, some of which are identified below. For reasons of brevity, for the remainder of this specification unless otherwise stated, the transaction fee is assumed to be a fixed percentage of the total amount traded over all the states.
cp represents the interest rate charged on margin loans.
cr represents the interest rate paid on trade balances.
t . represents time from the acceptance of a trade or investment to the fulfillment of all of the termination criteria for the group of DBAR contingent claims, typically expressed in years or fractions thereof.
X represents other information upon which the DRF or transaction fee can depend such as information specific to an investment or a trader, including for example the time or size of a trade.
In preferred embodiments, a DRF is a fiznction that takes the traded amounts over the distribution of states for a given group of DBAR contingent claims, the transaction fee schedule, and, conditional upon the occurrence of each state, computes the payouts to each trade or investment placed over the distribution of states. In notation, such a DRF is:
P = DRF(A, f(A,X), X ~ s=s;) = A* j~ (A, f(A,X), X) (DRF) In other words, the m traders who have placed trades across the n states, as represented in matrix A, will receive payouts as represented in matrix P should state i occur, also, taking into account the transaction fee f and other factors X. The payouts identified in matrix P can be represented as the product of (a) the payouts per unit traded for each state should each state occur, as identified in the matrix Tj, and (b) the matrix A which identifies the amounts traded or invested by each trader in each state. The following notation may be used to indicate that, in preferred embodiments, payouts should not exceed the total amounts invested less the transaction fee, irrespective of which state occurs:
lm * P,,~ + f (A, X) <= lm * A * 1" for j=l ..n (DRF Constraint) where the 1 represents a column vector with dimension indicated by the subscript, the superscript T represents the standard transpose operator and P=~ is the j-th column of the matrix P
representing the payouts to be made to each trader should state j occur. Thus, in preferred embodiments, the unsuccessful investments finance the successfi~l investments.
In addition, absent credit-related risks discussed below, in such embodiments there is no risk that payouts will exceed the total amount invested in the distribution of states, no matter what state occurs. In short, a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention is self financing in the sense that for any state, the payouts plus the transaction fee do not exceed the inputs (i.e., the invested amounts).
The DRF may depend on factors other than the amount of the investment and the state in which the investment was made. For example, a payout may depend upon the magnitude of a change in the observed outcome for an underlying event between two dates (e.g., the change in price of a security between two dates). As another example, the DRF may allocate higher payouts to traders who initiated investments earlier in the trading period than traders who invested later in the trading period, thereby providing incentives for liquidity earlier in the trading period. Alternatively, the DRF may allocate higher payouts to larger amounts invested in a given state than to smaller amounts invested for that state, thereby providing another liquidity incentive.
In any event, there are many possible functional forms for a DRF that could be used. To illustrate, one trivial form of a DRF is the case in which the traded amounts, A, are not reallocated at all upon the occurrence of any state, i.e., each trader receives his traded amount back in the event that any state occurs, as indicated by the following notation:
-~0-P = A if s=s;, for i=1 ..n This trivial DRF is not useful in allocating and exchanging risk among hedgers.
For a meaningful risk exchange to occur, a preferred embodiment of a DRF
should effect a meaningful reallocation of amounts invested across the distribution of states upon the occurrence of at least one state. Groups of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention are discussed in the context of a canonical DRF, which is a preferred embodiment in which the amounts invested in states which did not occur are completely reallocated to the state which did .
occur (less any transaction fee). The present invention is not limited to a canonical DRF, and many other types of DRFs can be used and may be preferred to implement a group of DBAR
contingent claims. For example, another DRF preferred embodiment allocates half the total amount. invested to the outcome state and rebates the remainder of the total amount invested to the states which did not occur. In another preferred embodiment, a DRF would allocate some percentage to an occurring. state, and some other percentage to one or more "nearby" or "adjacent" states with the bulk of the non-occurring states receiving zero payouts. Section 7 decribes an OPF for DBAR digital options which includes a DRF and determines investment amounts per investment or order along with allocating returns. Other DRFs will be apparent to those of skill in the art from review of this specification and practice of the present invention.
2.2 Units of Investments and Pa3routs The units of investments and payouts in systems and, methods of the present invention may be units of currency, quantities of commodities, numbers of shares of common stock, amount of a swap transaction or any other units representing economic value.
Thus, there is no limitation that the investments or payouts be in units of currency or money (e.g., U.S. dollars) or that the payouts resulting from the DRF be in the same units as the investments. Preferably, the same unit of value is used to represent the value of each investment, the total amount of all investments in a group of DBAR contingent claims, and the amounts invested in each state.
It is possible, for example, for traders to make investments in a group of DBAR
contingent claims in numbers of shares of common stock and for the applicable DRF (or OPF) to allocate payouts to traders in Japanese Yen or barrels of oil. Furthermore, it is possible for traded amounts and payouts to be some combination of units, such as, for example, a combination of commodities, currencies, and number of shares. In preferred embodiments traders need not physically deposit or receive delivery of the value units, and can rely upon the DBAR contingent claim exchange to convert between units for the purposes of facilitating efficient trading and payout transactions. For example, a DBAR contingent claim might be defined in such a way so that investments and payouts are to be made in ounces of gold. A trader can still deposit S currency, e.g., U.S. dollars, with the exchange and the exchange can be responsible for converting the amount invested in dollars into the correct units, e.g., gold, for the purposes of investing in a given state or receiving a payout. In this specification, a U.S. dollar is typically used as the unit of value for investments and payouts. This invention is not limited to investments or payouts in that value unit. In situations where investments and payouts are made in different units or combinations of units, for purpose of allocating.
returns to each investment the exchange preferably converts the amount of each investment, and thus the total of the investments in a group of DBAR contingent claims, into a single unit of value (e.g., dollars).
Example 3.1.20 below illustrates a group of DBAR contingent claims in which investments. and payouts are in units of quantities of common stock shares.
2.3 Canonical Demand Reallocation Function A preferred embodiment of a DRF that can be used to implement a group of DBAR
contingent claims is termed a "canonical" DRF. A canonical DRF is a type of DRF which has the following property: upon the occurrence of a given state i, investors who have invested in that state receive-a payout per unit invested equal to (a) the total amount traded for all the states .
less the transaction fee, divided by (b) the total amount invested in the occurring state. A
canonical DRF may employ a transaction fee which may be a fixed percentage of the total amount traded, T, although other transaction fees are possible. Traders who made investments in .
states which not did occur receive zero payout. Using the notation developed above:
~c;,~ _ (1 f ) * T if ice, i.e., the unit payout to an investment in state i if state i occurs T
~;,~ = 0 otherwise, i.e., if i~j, so that the payout is zero to investments in state i if state j occurs.
In a preferred embodiment of a canonical DRF, the unit payout matrix Tj as defined above is therefore a diagonal matrix with entries equal to ~;~ for i~ along the diagonal, and zeroes for all off diagonal entries. For example, in a preferred embodiment for n=S states, the unit payout matrix is:

T, T, Ti Ti II= 0 0 T 0 0 *(1-f)=0 0 1 0 0 *T*(1-f) Ta Ta TS TS

For this embodiment of a canonical DRF, the payout matrix is the total amount invested less the transaction fee, multiplied by a diagonal matrix which contains the inverse of the total amount invested in each state along the diagonal, respectively, aiid zeroes elsewhere. Both T, the total amount invested by all m traders across all n states, and T;, the total amount invested in state i, are functions of the matrix A, which contains the amount each trader has invested in each state:
T =lm *A*Bn(i) T =lm * A*ln where B"(i) is a column vector of dimension n which has a 1 at the i-th row and zeroes elsewhere.
Thus, with n=5 as an example, the canonical DRF described above has a unit payout matrix which is a function of the amounts traded across the states and the transaction fee:

lm *A*Bn(1) lm * A
* Bn (2) 0 0 * 0 0 *
*
*
*

II= lm *A (lf) Bn(3) 1n A
1n lm * A * Bn (4) lm' HT~n~~~
which can be generalized for any arbitrary number of states. The actual payout matrix, in the defined units of value for the group of DBAR contingent claims (e.g., dollars), is the product of S the m x n traded amount matrix A and the n x n unit payout matrix Tj, as defined above:
P = A * II(A, f ) (CDRF) This provides that the payout matrix as defined above is the matrix product of the amounts traded' as contained in the matrix A and'the unit payout matrix Tj, which is itself a function of the matrix A and the transaction fee, f. The expression is labeled CDRF for "Canonical Demand Reallocation Function."
It should be noted that, in this preferred embodiment, any change to the matrix A will generally have an effect on any given trader's payout, both due to changes in the amount invested, i.e., a direct effect through the matrix A in the CDRF, and changes in the unit payouts, i.e., an indirect effect since the unit payout matrix II is itself a function of the traded amount.
1 S matrix A.
2.4 Computing Investment Amounts to Achieve Desired Payouts In preferred embodiments of a group of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention, some traders make investments in states during the trading period in the expectation of a payout upon the occurrence of a given state, as expressed in the CDRF above.
Alternatively, a trader may have a preference for a desired payout distribution should a given state occur. DBAR
digital options, described in Section 6, are an example of an investment with a desired payout distribution should one or more specified states occur. Such a payout distribution could be denoted P;,*, which is a row corresponding to trader i in payout matrix P.
Such a trader may want to know how much to invest in contingent claims corresponding to a given state or states in order to achieve this payout distribution. In a preferred embodiment, the amount or amounts to be invested across the distribution of states for the CDRF, given a payout distribution, can be g_ obtained by inverting the expression for the CDRF and solving for the traded amount matrix A:
A = P * rt(A, f)-' (CDRF 2) In this notation, the -1 superscript on the unit payout matrix denotes a matrix inverse.
Expression CDRF 2 does not provide an explicit solution for the traded amount matrix A, since the unit payout matrix n is itself a function of the traded amount matrix. CDItF 2 typically involves the use of numerical methods to solve m simultaneous quadratic equations. For example, consider a trader who would like to know what amount, a, should be traded for a given.
state i in order to achieve a desired payout of p. Using the "forward"
expression to compute payouts from traded amounts as in CDRF above yields the following equation:
P_(T+a)*
a - T,. + a This represents a given row and column of the matrix equation CDRF.after a has been traded for . . : . . .
state i (assuming no transaction fee). This expression is, quadratic in .the traded amount a, and can be solved for the positive quadratic root as follows:
a-(P-T)+ (P-T)2+4*P*T (CDRF3) 2.5 A Canonical DRF Example A simplified example illustrates the use of the CDRF with a group of DBAR
contingent claims defined over two states (e.g., states "1" and "2") in which four traders make investments.
For the,example, the following assumptions are made: (1) the transaction fee, f, is zero; (2) the investment and payout units are both dollars; (3) trader 1 has made investments in the amount of $5 in state 1 and $10 state 2; and (4) trader 2 has made an investment in the amount of $7 for state 1 only. With the investment activity so far described, the traded amount matrix A, which as 4 rows and 2 columns, and the unit payout matrix ~ which has 2 rows and 2 columns, would be denoted as follows:

'7 0 A=

J
_1 0 n = 12 1 * 22 The payout matrix P, Which contains the payouts in dollars for each trader should each state occur is, the product of A and ~:
S
9.167 22 12.833 0 P

0. 0 'The first row of P corresponds to payouts to trader 1 based on his investments and the unit payout .
matrix. Should state 1 occur, trader lwill receive a payout of $9.167 and will receive $22 should state 2 occur. Similarly, trader 2 will receive $12.833 should.state 1 occur and $0 should state 2 10 occur (since trader 2 did not make any investment in state 2). In this illustration, traders 3 and 4 have $0 payouts since they have made. no investments.
In accordance with the expression above labeled "DRF Constraint," the total payouts to be made upon the occurrence of either state is less than or equal to the total amounts invested. In other words, the CDRF in this example is self financing so that total payouts plus the transaction fee (assumed to be zero in this example) do not exceed the total amounts invested, irrespective of which state occurs. This is indicated by the.following notation:
lm *P.1=22<lm *A*ln =22 lm *P.,Z =22<_lm *A*1" =22 Continuing with this example, it is now assumed that traders 3 and 4 each would like to make investments that generate a desired payout distribution. For example, it is assumed that trader 3 would like to receive a payout of $2 should state 1 occur and $4 should state 2 occur, while trader 4 would like to receive a payout of $5 should state 1 occur and $0 should state 2 occur. In the CDRF notation:
P3,. _ ~2 4~
P4,. _ ~5 0 In a preferred embodiment and this example, payouts are made based upon the invested amounts A, and therefore are also based on the unit payout matrix ~(A,f(A)), given the distribution of traded amounts as they exist at the end of the trading period.
For purposes of this example, it is now further assumed (a) that at the end of the trading period traders 1 and 2 have made investments as indicated above, and (b) that the desired payout distributions for traders 3 and 4 have been recorded in a suspense account which is used to determine the allocation of mufti-state investments to each state in order to achieve the desired payout distributions for each trader, given the investments by the other traders as they exist at the end of the trading period. In order to determine the proper allocation, the suspense account can be used to solve CDRF 2, for example:
5 . 10 P1,1 P1,2 1 0 * (5 + 7 + a 3,, + a 4,, ) 0 coot ' d P2,1 P2,z as,1 a.s.2 2 4 0 . 1 below a a 5 0 (10 +0+a3,2 +a4;z) 4,1 4,2 *(S+10+7+0+a3,, +cz4,, +a3,2 +a4,2) The solution of this expression will yield the amounts that traders 3 and 4 need to invest in for 1 S contingent claims corresponding to states 1 and 2 to in order to achieve their desired payout distributions, respectively. This solution will also finalize the total investment amount so that traders 1 and 2 will be able to determine their payouts should either state occur. This solution can be achieved using a computer program that computes an investment amount for each state for each trader in order to generate the desired payout for that trader for that state. In a preferred embodiment, the computer program repeats the process iteratively until the calculated investment amounts converge, i.e., so that the amounts to be invested by traders 3 and 4 no longer materially change with each successive iteration of the computational process. This method is known in the art as fixed point iteration and is explained in more detail in the Technical Appendix. The following table contains a computer code listing of two functions written in Microsoft's Visual Basic which can be used to perform the iterative calculations to compute the final allocations of the invested amounts in this example of a group of DBAR contingent claims with a Canonical Demand Reallocation Function:
Table 1: Illustrative Visual Basic Computer Code for Solvine CDRF 2 Function allocatetrades(A mat, P mat) As Variant Dim A final Dim trades As Long Dim states As Long trades = P mat.Rows.Count states= P mat.Columns.Count ReDim A final(1 To trades, l To states) ReIhm statedem(1 To states) Dim i As Long Dim totaldemand As Double Dim total desired As Double Dim iterations As Long iterations =10 For i = 1 To hades For j = l,To states statedem(j) = A mat(i, j) + statedem(j) A fmal(i, j) = A mat(i, j) Next j Next i For i = 1 To states totaldemand = totaldermnd + statedem(i) Next i For i =' 1 To iterations For j = 1 To trades For z = 1 To states If A mat(j, z) = 0 Then totaldemand = totaldemand - A final(j, z) statedem(z) = statedem(z) - A final(j, z) tempalloc = A fmal(j, z) A final(j, z) = stateall(totaldemand, P Imt(j, z), statedem(z)) totaldemand = A final(j, 2) + totaldemand statedem(z) = A fmal(j, z) + statedem(z) End If Next z Next j Next i allocatetrades = A final End Function Function stateall(totdemex, despaystate, totstateex) Dim soil As Double sol l = (-(totdemex - despaystate) + ((totdemex - despaystate) ~ 2 + 4 ~
despaystate ~ totstateex) ~ 0.5) / 2 .stateall = sol l End Function For this example involving two states and four traders; use of the computer code represented in Table 1 produces an investment amount matrix A, as follows:
l0 5 A=
1.1574 1.6852 2.8935 0 The matrix of unit payouts, II, can be computed from A as described above and is equal to:
1.728 0 II =
0 2.3736 The resulting payout matrix P is the product of A and ~ and is equal to: . . , 8.64 23.7361 P _ 12.0961 0 It can be noted. that the sum of each column of P, above is equal to 27.7361, which is equal (in dollars) to the total amount invested so, as desired in this example, the group of DBAR
contingent claims is self financing. The allocation is said to be in equilibrium, since the amounts invested by traders 1 and 2 are undisturbed, and traders 3 and 4 receive their desired payouts, as specified above, should each state occur.
2.6 Interest Considerations When investing in a group of DBAR contingent claims, traders will typically have outstanding balances invested for periods of time and may also have outstanding loans or margin balances from the exchange for periods of time. Traders will typically be paid interest on outstanding investment balances and typically will pay interest on outstanding margin loans. In preferred embodiments, the effect of trade balance interest and margin loan interest can be made explicit in the payouts, although in alternate preferred embodiments these items can be handled outside of the payout structure, for example, by debiting and crediting user accounts. So, if a fraction (3 of a trade of one value unit is made with cash and the rest on margin, the unit payout ~; in the event that state i occurs can be expressed as follows:
_6 _ (1 ~)*T +~*(Cr)*tb (1 ~)*(Cp)*tl ' T,.
where the last two terms express the respective credit for trade balances per unit invested for time tb and debit for margin loans per unit invested for time t~:
2.7 Returns and Probabilities In a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR contingent claims with a canonical DRF, returns which represent the percentage return per unit of investment are closely related to payouts. Such returns are also closely related to the notion of a financial return familiar to investors. For example, if an investor has purchased a stock for $100 and sells it for $114, then this investor has realized a return of 10% (and a payout of $110).
In a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR contingent claims with a canonical DRF, the unit return, r;, should state i occur may be expressed as follows:
(i- f)* ~T; -T
r; = T'"" if state i occurs r ri =-1 otherwise, i.e., if state i does not occur In such an embodiment, the return per unit investment in a state that occurs is a function of the amount invested in that state, the amount invested in all the other states and the exchange fee. The unit return is -100% for a state that does not occur, i.e., the entire amount invested in the expectation of receiving a return if a state occurs is forfeited if that state fails to occur. A -100% return in such an event has the same return profile as, for example, a traditional option expiring "out of the money." When a traditional option expires out of the money, the premium decays to zero, and the entire amount invested in the option is lost.
For purposes of this specification, a payout is defined as one plus the return per unit invested in a given state multiplied by the amount that has been invested in that state. The sum of all payouts PS, for a group of DBAR contingent claims corresponding to all n possible states can be expressed as follows:
PS = (1+ri)*T,. + ~(1+r~)*T~ i, j = 1..n l.Jxi In a preferred embodiment employing a canonical DRF, the payout PS may be found for the occurrence of state i by substituting the above expressions for the unit return in any state:
_7~_ (1- f)* ~T -T
,I,S -( ~=~..rs +1)*T + ~(-1+1)*T; =(1- f)* ~T,.
T ; ;,;~~ t=l..n Accordingly, in such a preferred embodiment, for the occurrence of any given state, no matter what state, the aggregate payout to all of the traders as a whole is one minus the transaction fee paid to the exchange (expressed in this preferred embodiment as a percentage of total investment across all the states), multiplied by the total amount invested across all the states for the group of DBAR contingent claiiris. This means that in a preferred embodiment of a group of the DBAR contingent claims, and assuming no credit or similar risks to the exchange, (1) the exchange has zero probability of loss in any given state; (2) for the occurrence of any given state, the exchange receives an exchange fee and is not exposed to any risk; (3) payouts and returns are a function of demand flow, i.e., amounts invested; and (4) transaction fees.
or exchange fees can be a simple function of aggregate amount invested.
Other transaction fees can be implemented. For example, the transaction fee might have a 1 S fixed component for some level of aggregate amount invested and then have either a sliding or fixed percentage applied to the amount of the investment in excess of this level. Other methods for determining the transaction fee are apparent to those of skill in the art, from this specification or based on practice of the present invention.
In a preferred embodiment, the total distribution of amounts invested in the various states also implies an assessment by all traders collectively of the probabilities of occurrence of each state. . In a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR contingent claims with a canonical DRF, the expected return E(r; ) for an investment in a given state i {as opposed to the return actually received once outcomes are known) may be expressed as the probability weighted sum of the returns:
E(n)=q; *r; +(1-q;)*-1=q; *(1+r;)-1 Where q; is the probability of the occurrence of state i implied by the matrix A (which contains all of the invested amounts for all states in the group of DBAR contingent claims). Substituting the expression for r; from above yields:

(i-l)*~T;
E(r;)=9; "( ~ T ' )-1 ' In an efficient market, the expected return E(r;) across all states is equal to the transaction costs of trading, i.e., on average, all traders collectively earn returns that do not exceed the costs of trading. Thus, in an e~cient market for a group of DBAR contingent claims using a canonical, where E(r) equals the transaction fee, -f, the probability of the occurrence of state i implied by matrix A is computed to be:
. --~T
' Thus; in such a group of DBAR contingent claims, the implied probability of a' given state is the ratio of the amount invested in that state divided by the total amount invested in all states.
This relationship allows traders in the group of DBAR contingent claims (with a canonical DRF) readily to calculate the implied probability which traders attach to the various states.
Information of interest to a trader typically includes the amounts invested per state, the unit return per state, and implied state probabilities. An advantage of the DBAR exchange of the present invention is the relationship among these quantities. In a preferred embodiment, if the trader knows 'one, the other two can be readily determined. For example, the relationship of unit returns fo the occurrence of a state and the probability of the occurrence of that state implied by A can be expressed as follows:
(i-f) 9t=(1+r;).
The expressions derived above show that returns and implied state probabilities may be calculated from the distribution of the invested amounts, T;, for all states, i= l ..n. In the traditional markets, the amount traded across the distribution of states (limit order book), is not readily available. Furthermore, in traditional markets there are no such ready mathematical calculations that relate with any precision invested amounts or the limit order book to returns or prices which clear the market, i.e., prices at which the supply equals the demand. Rather, in the traditional markets, specialist brokers and market makers typically have privileged access to the distribution of bids and offers, or the limit order book, and frequently use this privileged information in order to set market prices that balance supply and demand at any given time in the judgment of the market maker.

2.8 Computations When Invested Amounts Are Large In a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR contingent claims using a canonical DRF, when large amounts are invested across the distribution of states, it may be possible to perform approximate investment allocation calculations in order to generate desired payout distributions. The payout, p, should state i occur for a trader who considers making an investment of size a in state i has been shown above to be:
p_~T+a~*
a T,. + a If a is small compared to both the total invested in state i and the total amount invested in all the states, then adding a to state i will not have a material effect on the ratio of the total amount invested in all the states to the total amount invested in state i. In these circumstances, T+a T
T; + a T;
Thus, in preferred embodiments where an approximation .is acceptable, the payout to state i may be expressed as:
p ~ T *a T
In these circumstances, the investment needed to generate the payout p is:
a~ T~ *P=9; *P
These expressions indicate that in preferred embodiments, the amount to be invested to generate a desired payout is approximately equal to the ratio of the total amount invested in state i to the total amount invested in all states, multiplied by the desired payout. This is equivalent to the implied probability multiplied by the desired payout. Applying this approximation to the expression CDRF 2, above, yields the following:
A~ P*II ' =P*Q
where the matrix Q, of dimension n x n, is equal to the inverse of unit payouts TI, and has along the diagonals q;.for i= 1..n. This expression provides an approximate but more readily calculable solution to CDRF 2 as the expression implicitly assumes that an amount invested by a trader has approximately no effect on the existing unit payouts or implied probabilities.
This approximate solution, which is linear and not quadratic, will sometimes be used in the following examples where it can be assumed that the total amounts invested are large in relation to any given trader's particular investment.
3. EXAMPLES OF GROUPS OF DBAR CONTINGENT CLAIMS
3.1 DBAR Range Derivatives A DBAR Range Derivative (DBAR RD) is a type of group of DBAR contingent claims implemented using a canonical DRF described above (although a DBAR range derivative can also be implemented, for example, for a group of DBAR contingent claims, including DBAR
digital options, based on the same ranges and economic events established below using, e.g., a non-canonical DRF and an OPF). In a DBAR RD, a range of possible outcomes associated with an observable event of economic significance is partitioned into defined states. In a preferred embodiment, the states are defined as discrete ranges of possible outcomes so that the entire distribution of states covers all the possible outcomes -- that is, the states are collectively exhaustive. Furthermore, in a DBAR RD, states are preferably defined so as to be mutually exclusive as well, meaning that the states are defined in such a way so that exactly one state occurs. If the states are defined to be both mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive, the states form the basis of a probability distribution defined over discrete outcome ranges. Defining the states in this way has many advantages as described below, including the advantage that the amount which traders invest across the states can be readily converted into implied probabilities representing the collective assessment of traders as to the likelihood of the occurrence of each state.
The system and methods of the present invention may also. be applied to determine projected DBAR RD returns for various states at the beginning of a trading period. Such a determination can be, but need not be, made by an exchange. In preferred embodiments of a ' group of DBAR contingent claims the distribution of invested amounts at the end of a trading period determines the returns for each state, and the amount invested in each state is a function of trader preferences and probability assessments of each state. Accordingly, some assumptions typically need to be made in order to determine preliminary or projected returns for each state at the beginning of a trading period.
An illustration is provided to explain further the operation of DBAR RDs. In the following illustration, it is assumed that all traders are risk neutral so that implied probabilities for a state are equal to the actual probabilities, and so that all traders have identical probability assessments of the possible outcomes for the event defining the contingent claim. For _7~_ convenience in this illustration, the event forming the basis for the contingent claims is taken to be a closing price of a security, such as a common stock, at some future date;
and the states, which represent the possible outcomes of the level of the closing price, are defined to be distinct, mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive of the range of (possible) closing prices for the security. ~ In this illustration, the following notation is used:
T . represents a given time during the trading period at which traders are making investment decisions 8 represents the time corresponding to the expiration of the contingent claim V~ represents the price of underlying security at time i Ve represents the price of underlying security at time 8 Z(i,8) represents the present value of one unit of value payable at time A
evaluated at time i D(i,A) represents dividends or coupons payable between time i and A' a~ represents annualized volatility of natural logarithm returns of the underlying security dz represents the standard normal variate Traders make choices at a representative time,.i, during a trading period which is open, so that time z is aemporally subsequent to the current trading period's TSD.
-In this illustration, and in preferred embodiments, the defined states for the group of contingent claims for the final closing price Ve are constructed by discretizing the full range of possible prices into possible mutually exclusive and Collectively exhaustive states. The technique is similar to forming a histogram for discrete countable data. The endpoints of each state can be chosen, for example, to be equally spaced, or of varying spacing to reflect the reduced likehood of extreme outcomes compared to outcomes near the mean or median of the distribution. States may also be defined in other manners apparent to one of skill in the art. The lower endpoint of a state can be included and the upper endpoint excluded, or vice versa. In any event, in preferred embodiments, the states are defined (as explained below) to maximize the attractiveness of investment in the group of DBAR contingent claims, since it is the invested amounts that ultimately determine the returns that are associated with each defined state.
The procedure of defining states, for example for a stock price, can be accomplished by assuming lognormality, by using statistical estimation techniques based on historical time series S data and cross-section market data from options prices, by using other statistical distributions, or according to other procedures known to one of skill in the art or learned from this specification or .
through practice of the present invention. For example, it is quite common among derivatives traders to estimate volatility parameters for the purpose of pricing options by using the econometric techniques such as GARCH. Using these parameters and the known dividend or coupons over the time period from i to B, for example, the states for a DBAR
RD can be defined.
A lognonmal distribution is chosen for this illustration since it is commonly employed by derivatives traders as a distributional assumption for the purpose of evaluating the prices of options and other derivative securities. Accordingly, for purposes of this illustration it is assumed that all traders agree that the underlying distribution of states for the security are lognonrnally distributed such that:
y~B = ( Vr - D(z~ e) ) * e-~ i 2~~e-~>: * e~~ e-~~~
Z(z, 8) Z(z, B) where the "tilde" on the left-hand side of the expression indicates that the final closing price of the value of the security at time 8 is yet to be known. Inversion of the expression for dz and discretization of ranges yields the following expressions:
~z V * a i ~ce_z>
dz=ln(( ~ -D(z~e)))l(a* 6-z) r Z(z, 8) Z(z, B) q; (Y,. <= VB < V,.+i ) = cd_ f'(dz;+, ) - cdf (dz; ) r; (V <= YB < Y,.+~ ) _ (1 'f ). -1 qr (V <= VB < V~+i ) where cdf(dz) is the cumulative standard normal function.
The assumptions and calculations reflected in the expressions presented above can also be used to calculate indicative returns ("opening returns"), r; at a beginning of the trading period for a given group of DBAR contingent claims. 1n a preferred embodiment, the calculated opening returns are based on the exchange's best estimate of the probabilities for the states defining flee _7 claim and therefore may provide good indications to traders of likely returns once trading is underway. In another preferred embodiment, described with respect to DBAR
digital options in Section 6 and another embodiment described in Section 7, a very small number of value units may be used in each state to initialize the contract or group of contingent claims. Of course, opening returns need not be provided at all, as traded amounts placed throughout the trading period allows the calculation of actual expected returns at any time during the trading period.
The following examples of DBAR range derivatives and other contingent claims serve to illustrate their operation, their usefulness in connection with a variety of events of economic significance involving inherent risk or uncertainty, the advantages of exchanges for groups of DBAR. contingent claims, and, more generally, systems and methods of the present invention.
Sections 6 and 7 also provide examples of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention that . .
provide profit and loss scenarios comparable to those provided by digital options in conventional ,.
options markets, and that can be based on any of the variety of events of economic signficance described in the following examples of DBAR RDs.
In each of the examples in this Section, a state is defined to include a range of possible outcomes of an event of economic significance. The event of economic significance for any DBAR auction or market (including any market or auction for DBAR digital options) can be, for example, an underlying economic event (e.g., price of stock) or a measured parameter related to the underlying economic event (e.g., a measured volatility of the price of stock). A curved brace "(" or ")" denotes strict inequality (e.g., "greater than" or "less than,"
respectively ) and a square brace "]" or "[" shall denote weak inequality (e.g., "less than or equal to"
or "greater than or equal to," respectively). For simplicity, and unless otherwise stated, the following examples also assume that the exchange transaction fee, f, is zero.
Example 3.1.1: DBAR Continent Claim On Underlying Common Stock Underlying Security: Microsoft Corporation Common Stock ("MSFT") Date: 8/ 18/99 Spot Price: 85 Market Volatility: 50% annualized Trading Start Date: 8/18/99, Market Open 'trading End Date: 8/18/99, Market Close _77_ Expiration: 8/19/99, Market Close Event: MSFT Closing Price at Expiration Trading Time: 1 day Duration to TED: 1 day Dividends Payable to Expiration: 0 Interbank short-term interest rate to Expiration: S.5% (Actual/360 daycount) Present Value factor to Expiration: 0.999847 Investment and Payout Units: U.S. Dollars ("USD") . _ In this Example 3.1.1, the predetermined termination criteria are the investment in. a contingent claim during the trading period and the closing of the market for Microsoft common stock on 8/19/99.
If all traders agree that the underlying distribution of closing prices is lognormally ' distributed with volatility of 50%, then an illustrative "snapshot"
distribution of invested amounts.. .
and returns for $100 million of aggregate investment can be readily calculated to yield the following table.. .
Table 3.1.1-1 - States Investment in Return Per Unit if State State ('000) Occurs (0,80) 1,046.58 94.55 (80,80.5]870.67 113.85 (80.5,81]1,411.35 69.85 (81,81.5]2,157.85 45.34 (81.5,82]3,115.03 31.1 (82,82.5]4,250.18 22.53 (82.5,83]5,486.44 17.23 (83,83.5]6,707.18 13.91 (83.5,84]7,772.68 11.87 (84,84.5]8,546.50 10.7 (84.5,85]8,924.71 10.2 (85,85.5)8,858.85 10.29 (85.5,86]8,366.06 10.95 (86,86.5]7,523.13 12.29 (86.5,87]6,447.26 14.51 (87,87.5]5,270.01 17.98 (87.5,88]4,112.05 23.31 (88,88.5]3,065.21 31.62 (88.5,89]2,184.5 44.78 (89,89.5]1,489.58 66.13 I

_7g_ (89.5,90) I 972.56 I 101.82 (90,aoJ 1,421.61 69.34 Consistent with the design of a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR
contingent claims, the amount invested for any given state is inversely related to the unit return for that state.
In preferred embodiments of groups of DBAR contingent claims, traders can invest in none, one or many states. It may be possible in preferred embodiments to allow traders efficiently to invest in a set, subset or combination of states for the purposes of generating desired distributions of payouts across the states. In particular, traders may be interested in replicating payout distributions which are common in the traditional markets, such as payouts corresponding to a long stock position, a short futuies position, a long option straddle position, a digital put or digital call option.
If in this Example 3.1.1 a trader desired to hedge his exposure to extreme outcomes in MSFT stock, then the trader could invest in states at each end of the distribution of possible outcomes. For instance, a trader might decide to invest $100,000 in states encompassing prices from $0 up to and including $83 (i.e., (0,83]) and another $100,000 in states encompassing prices greater than $86.50 (i.e., (86.S,oo]). The trader may further desire that no matter what state actually occurs within these ranges (should the state occur in either range) upon the fulfillment of the predetermined termination criteria, an identical payout will result. In this Example 3.1.1, a mufti-state investment is effectively a group of single state investments over each mufti-state range, where an amount is invested in each state in the range in proportion to the amount previously invested in that state. If, for example, the returns provided in Table 3.1.1-1 represent finalized projected returns at the end'of the trading period, then each mufti-state investment may be allocated to its constituent states on a pro-rata or proportional basis according to the relative amounts invested in the constituent states at the close of trading. In this way, more of the multi-state investment is allocated to states with larger investments and less allocated to the states with smaller investments.
Other desired payout distributions across the states can be generated by allocating the amount invested among the constituent states in different ways so as achieve a trader's desired payout distribution. A trader may select, for example, both the magnitude of the payouts and how those payouts are to be distributed should each state occur and let the DBAR exchange's mufti-state allocation methods determine (1) the size of the amount invested in each particular constituent state; (2) the states in which investments will be made, and (3) how much of the total _7 amount to be invested will be invested in each of the states so determined.
Other examples below demonstrate how such selections may be implemented.
Since in preferred embodiments the final projected returns are not known until the end of a given trading period, in such embodiments a previous mufti-state investment is reallocated to S its constituent states periodically as the amounts invested in each state (and therefore returns) change during the trading period. At the end of the trading period when trading ceases and . -projected returns are finalized, in a preferred embodiment a final reallocation is made o:f;all the mufti-state investments. In preferred embodiments, a suspense account is used to record and reallocate mufti-state investments during the course of trading and at the end of the trading period.
Referring back to the illustration assuming two mufti-state trades over the ranges (0;83]
and (86.5,x] for MSFT stock, Table 3.1.1-2 shows how the mufti-state investments in the amount of $100,000 each could be allocated according to a preferred embodiment to the individual states over each range in order to achieve a payout for each mufti-state range which is identical ..
1 S regardless of which state occurs within each range. In particular, in this illustration the multi-state investments are allocated in proportion to the previously invested amount in each.state, and the mufti-state investments marginally lower returns over (0,83] and (86.S,oo], but marginally increase returns over the range (83, 86.5), as expected.
To show, that the allocation in this example has achieved its goal of delivering the desired payouts to the trader, two payouts for the (0, 83] range are considered. The payout, if constituent state (80.5; 81 ] occurs, is the amount invested in that state ($7.696) multiplied by one plus the return per unit if that state occurs, or (1+69.61)*7.696=$543.40. A similar analysis for the state (82.5, 83] shows that, if it occurs, the payout is equal to (1+17.162)*29.918=
$543.40: Thus, in this illustration, the trader receives the same payout no matter which constituent state occurs.
within the mufti-state investment. Similar calculations can.be performed for the range [86.S;oo].
For example, under the same assumptions, the payout for the constituent state [86.5,87] would receive a,payout of $399.80 if the stock price fill in that range after the fulfillment of all of the predetermined termination criteria. In this illustration, each constituent state over the range [86.5, oo] would receive a payout of $399.80, no matter which of those states occurs.

Table 3.1.1-2 .
States Traded Amount in Return Per Unit if Multi-State Allocation State State Occurs f 000) f 000) (0,80] 1052.29. 94.22 5.707 (80,80.5]875.42 113.46 4.748 (80.5,81]1,419.05 69.61 7.696 (81,81.5]2,169.61 45.18 11.767 (81.5,82]3,132.02. 30.99 16.987 (82,82.5]4,273.35 22.45 23.177 (82.5,83]5,516.36 17.16 29.918 (83,83.5]..6,707.1.8. 13.94 (83.5,84]7,772.68 11.89 (84,84.5]8,546.50 10.72 .,(84.5,85)8,924.71: 10.23 (85,85.5]8,858.85 10.31 (85:5,86]8,366.06 . . 10.98 (86,86.5]7,523:13 12.32 (86.5,87]6,473.09 14.48 25.828 (87,87.5]5,291.12 17.94 21.111 (87.5,88]4,128.52 23.27 16:473 (88,88.5]3,077.49 31.56 12.279 (88.5,89]2,193.25 44.69 8.751 (89,89.5]1,495.55. 66..00 5.967 _ (89.5,90}976.46 101.62 3.896 (90,00]1,427.31 69:20 5.695 Options on equities and equity indices have been one of the more successful innovations in the capital markets. Currently, listed options products exist for various underlying equity securities and indices and for various individual option series.
Unfortunately, certain markets lack liquidity. Specifically, liquidity is usually limited to only a handful of the most widely recognized names. Most option markets are essentially dealer-based. Even for options listed on an exchange, market-makers who stand ready to buy or sell options across all strikes and maturities are a necessity. Although market participants trading a particular option share an interest in only one underlying equity, the existence of numerous strike prices scatters liquidity coming into the market thereby making dealer support essential. In all but the 'most liquid and active exchange-traded options, chances are rare that two option orders will meet for the same strike, at the same price, at the same time, and for the same volume.
Moreover, market-makers in listed and over-the-counter (OTC) equities must allocate capital and manage risk for all their - ~1 -positions. Consequently, the absolute amount of capital that any one market-maker has on hand is naturally constrained and may be insufficient to meet the volume of institutional demand.
The utility of equity and equity-index options is further constrained by a lack of transparency in the OTC markets. Investment banks typically offer customized option structures to satisfy their customers. Customers, however, are sometimes hesitant to trade in environments .
where they have no means of viewing the market and so are uncertain about getting the best prevailing price.
Groups of DBAR contingent claims can be structured using the system and methods of the present invention to provide market participants with a fuller, more precise view of the price for risks associated with a particular equity.
Example 3.1.2: Multiple Mufti-State Investments If numerous mufti-state investments are made for a group of DBAR contingent claims, then in a.preferred embodiment an iterative procedure can be employed to allocate all of the mufti-state investments to their respective constituent states. In preferred embodiments, the goal would be to allocate each mufti-state investment in response to changes in amounts invested during the trading period, and to make a final allocation at the end of the trading period so that each mufti-state investment generates the payouts desired by the respective trader. In preferred embodiments, the process of allocating mufti-state investments can be iterative, since allocations depend upon the amounts traded across the distribution of states at any point in time. As a consequence, in preferred embodiments, a given distribution of invested amounts will result in a certain allocation of a mufti-state investment. When another mufti-state investment is allocated, the distribution of invested amounts across the defined states may change and therefore necessitate the reallocation of any previously allocated mufti-state investments. In such preferred embodiments, each mufti-state allocation is re-performed so that, after a number of iterations through all of the pending mufti-state investments, both the amounts invested and their allocations among constituent states in the mufti-state investments no longer change with each successive iteration and a convergence is achieved. In preferred embodiments, when convergence is achieved, further iteration and reallocation among the mufti-state investments do not change any mufti-state allocation, and the entire distribution of amounts invested across the states remains stable and is said to be in equilibrium. Computer code, as illustrated in Table 1 _82_ above or related code readily apparent to one of skill in the art, can be used to implement this iterative procedure.
A simple example demonstrates a preferred embodiment of an iterative procedure that may be employed. For purposes of this example, a preferred embodiment of the following S assumptions are made: (i) there are four defined states for the group of DBAR contingent claims;
(ii) prior to the allocation of any mufti-state investments, $100 has been invested in each state so that the unit return for each of the four states is 3; (iii) each desires that each constituent state in a mufti-state investment provides the same payout regardless of which constituent state actually.
occurs; and (iv) that the following other mufti-state investments have been made:
-~3-Table 3.1.2-1 Investment Invested Number State State State State Amount, 1 2 3 4 $

1.002 X 0 X X 5 1004 X X X 0 1.6 1006 0 0 . X X 21 . . 1007 X X X 0 8 1015 0 X X ~ 0 17 1019 X X X 0 25 .

1022 X 0 X X ~ 40d where an "X" in each state represents a constituent state of the multi-state trade. Thus, as depicted in Table 3.1.2-1, trade number 1401 in the first row is a mufti-state investment of $100 to be allocated among constituent states 1 and 2, trade number 1002 in the second row is another mufti-state investment in the amount of $50 to be allocated among constituent states 1, 3, and 4;
etc.
Applied to the illustrative mufti-state investment described above, the iterative procedure described above and embodied in the illustrative computer code in Table 1, results in the following allocations:
_ g~ _ Table 3.1.2-2 Investment Number State State State State 1 $ 2 $ 3 $ 4 $

1001 73.839 26.160 1002 26.6678 12.5336. 10.7985 88.607531.3924 __ 87.705931.0730 41.2209 _ 1005 98.66921. 34.9572146.3735 1006 112.808197.1918 1007 43.852915.5365 20.6104 1008 506.688 238.138205.172 1009 548.162194.206 257.631 1010 284.2_1100.694 115.087 Z

1011 177.94 72.05 1012 73.839 26.160 1013 340.138 159.861 _10_14 466.648 533.351 1015 73.0685 96.93141 1016 55.9978 64.0021 1017 680.276 319.723 1018 107.43692.5636 1019 137.04048.5516 64.4077 1020 170.53060.4167 69.0526 1021 28.8224 38.235232.9422 1022 213.342 100.26886.3884 In Table 3.1.2-2 each row shows the allocation among the constituent states of the mufti-state investment enteied into the corresponding row of Table 3.1.2-1, the first row of Table 3.1.2-2 5 that investment number 1001 in the amount of $100 has been allocated $73.8396 to state 1 and the remainder to state 2.
It may be shown that the mufti-state allocations identified above result in payouts-to traders which are desired by the traders -- that is, in this example the desired payouts are the same regardless of which state occurs among the constituent states of a given mufti-state 10 investment. Based on the total amount invested as reflected in Table 3.1.2-2 and assuming a zero transaction fee, the unit returns for each state are:
tate tate tate State Retum Per Dollar Invested 1.229 5.2921 3.74314.505 Consideration of Investment 1022 in this example, illustrates the uniformity of payouts for each state in which an investment is made (i.e., states 1, 3 and 4). If state 1 occurs, the total payout to the trader is the unit return for state 1 -- 1.2292 -- multiplied by the amount traded for state 1 in trade 1022 -- $213.3426 -- plus the initial trade -- $213.3426. This equals 1.2292*2I3.3426 +
213.3426 = $475.58. If state 3 occurs, the payout is equal to 3.7431 *
100.2689 +100.2689 =
$475.58. Finally, if state 4 occurs, the payout is equal to 4.5052*86.38848+
86.38848= $4?5.58.
So a preferred embodiment of a mufti-state allocation in this example has effected an allocation S among the constituent states so that (1) the desired payout distributions in this example are achieved, i.e., payouts to constituent states are the same no matter which constituent state occurs, and (2) further reallocation iterations of mufti-state investments do not change the relative amounts invested across the distribution of states for all the mufti-state trades.
1U ~ Example 3.1.3: Alternate Price Distributions Assumptions regarding the likely distribution of traded amounts for a group of DBAR
contingent claims may be used, for example, to compute returns for each defined state per unit of amount invested at the beginning of a trading period ("opening returns"). For various reasons, the amount actually invested in each defined state may not reflect the assumptions used to 15 calculate the opening returns. For instance, investors may speculate that the empirical distribution of returns over the time horizon may differ from the no-arbitrage assumptions typically used in option pricing. Instead of a lognormal distribution, more investors might make investments expecting returns to be significantly positive rather than negative (perhaps expecting favorable news). In Example 3.1.1, for instance, if traders invested more in states above $85 for 20 the price of MSFT common stock, the returns to states below $85 could therefore be significantly higher than returns to states above $85.
In addition, it is well known to derivatives traders that traded option prices indicate that price distributions differ markedly from theoretical lognormality or similar theoretical distributions. The so-called volatility skew or "smile" refers to out-of the-money put and call 25 options trading at higher implied volatilities than options closer to the money. This indicates that traders often expect the distribution of prices to have greater frequency_or mass at the extreme observations than predicted according to lognormal distributions. Frequently, this effect is not symmetric so that, for example, the probability of large lower price outcomes are higher than for extreme upward outcomes. Consequently, in a group of DBAR contingent claims of the present 30 invention, investment in states in these regions may be more prevalent and, therefore, finalized returns on outcomes in those regions lower. For example, using the basic DBAR
contingent claim information from Example 3.1.1, the following returns may prevail due to investor _g6_ expectations of return distributions that have more frequent occurrences than those predicted by a lognonmal distribution, and thus are skewed to the lower possible returns. In statistical parlance, such a distribution exhibits higher kurtosis and negative skewness iri returns than the illustrative distribution used in Example 3.1.1 and reflected in Table 3.1.1-1.
S
Table 3.1.3-1: DBAR Contingent Claim Returns Illustrating Ne atively Skewed and Leptokurtotic Return Distribution StatesAmount Invested Return Per Unit if in State('000) State Occurs (0,80]3,150 30.746 (80,80.5]1,500 65.667 (80.5,81]1,600 61.5 (81,81.5]1,750 56.143 (81.5,82)2,100 46.619 (82,82.5]2,550 38.216 (82.5,83]3,150 30.746 (83,83.5]3,250 29.769 (83.5,84]3,050 31.787 (84,84.5]8,800 10.363 (84.5,85]14,300 5.993 .

(85,85.5]10,950 8.132 (85.5,86]11,300 7.85 (86,86.5]10,150 8.852 (86.5,87]11,400 7.772 (87,87.5]4,550 20.978 (87.5,88]1,350 73.074 (88,88.5]1,250 79.0 (88.5,89]1,150 85.957 (89,89.5]700 141.857 (89.5,90]650 152.846 (90,00]1,350 73.074 The type of complex distribution illustrated in Table 3.1.3-1 is prevalent in the traditional markets. Derivatives traders, actuaries, risk managers and other traditional market participants typically use sophisticated mathematical and analytical tools in order to estimate the statistical nature of future distributions of risky market outcomes. These tools often rely on data sets (e.g., historical time series, options data) that may be incomplete or unreliable. An advantage of the systems and methods of the present invention is that such analyses from historical data need not be complicated, and the full outcome distribution for a group of DBAR
contingent claims based _g7_ on any given event is readily available to all traders and other interested parties nearly instantaneously after each investment.
Example 3.1.4: States Defined For Return Uniformitx It is also possible in preferred embodiments of the present invention to define states for a group of DBAR contingent claims with irregular or unevenly distributed intervals, for example, to make the traded amount across the states more liquid or uniform. States can be constructed from a likely estimate of the final distribution of invested amounts in order to make the likely invested amounts, and hence the returns for each state, as uniform as possible across the distribution of states. The following table illustrates the freedom, using the event and trading period from Example 3.1.1, to define states so as to promote equalization of the amount likely to be invested in each state.
Table 3.1.4-1: State Definition to Make Likely Demand Uniform Across States States Invested Amount in Return Per Unit if _ State ('000) State Occurs (0,81.403]5,000 19 (81.403,82.181]5,000 19 (82.181,82.71]5,000 19 -(82.71,83.132}5,000 19 (83.132,83.497]5,000 19 (83.497,83.826]5,000 19 (83.826,84.131]5,000 19 (84.131,84.422]5,000 19 (84.422,84.705]5,000 19 (84.705,84.984]5,000 19 (84.984,85.264]5,000 19 (SS.264,8S.S49]5,000 19 (85.549,8S.84S]5,000 19 (8S.84S,86.158]5,000 - i9 .

(86.158,86.497]5,000 19 (86.497,86.877]5,000 19 (86.877,87.321]5,000 19 (87.321,87.883]5,000 19 (87.883,88.722]5,000 - , i9_ (88.722, 5,000 19 oo]

1 S If investor expectations coincide with the often-used assumption of the lognormal distribution, as reflected in this example, then investment activity in the group of contingent claims reflected in Table 3.1.4-lwill converge to investment of the same amount in each of the _gg_ 20 states identified in the table. Of course, actual trading will likely yield final market returns which deviate from those initially chosen for convenience using a lognormal distribution.
Example 3.1.5: Government Bond -- Uniformly Constructed States The event, defined states, predetermined termination criteria and other relevant data for an illustrative group of DBAR contingent claims based on a U.S. Treasury Note are set forth below:
Underlying Security: United States Treasury Note, S.S%, 5/31/03 Bond Settlement Date: 6/25/99 . Bond Maturity Date: 5/31/03 Contingent Claim Expiration: 7/2/99, Market Close, 4:00 p.m. EST
Trading Period Start Date: 6/25/99, 4:00 p.m., EST
Trading Period End Date: 6/28/99, 4:00 p:ni.; EST
Next Trading Period Open: 6/28/99, 4:00 p.m., EST
. Next Trading Period Close 6/29/99, 4:00 p.m., EST
Event: Closing Composite Price as reported on Bloomberg at Claim Expiration Trading Time: 1 day Duration from TED: S days Coupon: 5.5%
~ Payment Frequency: Semiannual Daycount Basis: Actual/Actual Dividends Payable over Time Horizon: 2:75 per 100 on 6/30/99 Treasury note repo rate over Time Horizon: 4.0% (Actual/360 daycount) Spot Price: 99.8125 Forward Price at Expiration: 99.7857 Price Volatility: 4.7%
Trade and Payout Units: U.S. Dollars Total Demand in Current Trading Period: $50 million Transaction Fee: 25 basis points (.0025%) _g~_ Table 3.1.5-1: DBAR Contingent Claims on U.S. Government Note States Investment in State Unit Return if State ($) Occurs (0,98] 139690.1635 356.04 (98,98.25]293571.7323 168.89 (98.25,98.5]733769.9011 66.97 (98.5,98.75]1574439.456 30.68 (98.75,99]2903405.925 16.18 (99,99.1) 1627613.865 29:64 (99.1, 1914626.631 25.05 99.2]

(99.2, 2198593.057 21.68 99.3]

(99.3, 2464704.885 19.24 99.4]

(99.4, 2697585.072 17.49 99.5]

(99.5, 2882744.385 16.30 99.6) (99.6, 3008,078.286 '15.58 99.7]

,(99.7, 3065194.576 15.27 99.8) (99.8, 3050276.034 15.35 99.9) (99.9,100]2964602.039 15.82 ( 100, 2814300.657 1.6.72 100.1 ]

(100.1, 2609637.195 18:11 100.2]

(100.2, 2363883.036 20.10 100.3]

(100.3, 2091890.519 22.84 100.4]

(100.4, 1808629.526 26.58 100.5]

(100.5, 3326547.254 13.99 100.75]

(100.75,101]1899755.409 25.25 (101,101.25)941506.1374 51.97 ( 101.25,101.5]405331.6207 122.05 (101.5, 219622.6373 226:09 ooJ

This Example 3.1.5 and Table 3.1.5-1 illustrate how readily the methods and systems of the present invention may be adapted to sources of risk, whether from stocks, bonds, or insurance claims.; Table 3.1.5-1 also illustrates a distribution of defined states .which is irregularly spaced -in this case finer toward the center of the distribution and coarser at the ends -- in order to increase the amount invested in the extreme states.
Example 3.1.6: Outperformance Asset Allocation -- Uniform Range One of the advantages of the system and methods of the present invention is the ability to construct groups of DBAR contingent claims based on multiple events and their inter-relationships. For example, many index fund money managers often have a fundamental view as to whether indices of high quality fixed income securities will outperform major equity indices.

Such opinions normally are contained within a manager's model fox allocating funds under management between the major asset classes such as fixed income securities, equities, and cash.
This Example 3.1.6 illustrates the use of a preferred embodiment of the systems and methods of the present invention to hedge the real-world event that one asset class will outperform another. The illustrative distribution of investments and calculated opening returns for the group of contingent claims used in this example are based on the assumption that the . levels of the relevant asset-class indices are jointly Iognormally distributed with an assumed correlation. By defining a.group of DBAR contingent claims on a joint outcome of two underlying events, traders are able to express their views on the co-movements of the underlying events as captured by the statistical correlation between the events. In this example, the assumption of a joint lognormal distribution means that the two underlying events are distributed as follows:
Y~ _ ~ V ~ _ D~ Cz~ B)) ~ e-~~2 /2*ce_T) * e~~* e-z*~~
ZI Cz~ e) Z
Yg = ~ v2 - D2 ~Z~ e)) * a ~zz /2*~e ~) * e~z* e-T *~z Z2 ~Z~ e) Z2 ~Z~ e) 1 * (dz; +d~ -2* p*dz, *dz,) g(dzmdzz)= 2*~* 1- p2 exp(- 2*(1-p2) ) where the subscripts and superscripts indicate each of the two events, and g(dz,,dz2) is the bivariate normal distribution with correlation parameter p, and the notation otherwise corresponds to the notation used in the description above of DBAR Range Derivatives.
The following information includes the indices, the trading periods, the predetermined termination criteria, the total amount invested and the value units used in this Example 3.1.6:
Asset Class 1: JP Morgan United States Government Bond Index ("JPMGBI") Asset Class 1 Forward Price at Observation: 250.0 Asset Class 1 Volatility: 5%
Asset Class 2: S&P 500 Equity Index ("SP500") Asset Class 2 Forward Price at Observation: 1410 Asset Class 2 Volatility: 18%
_91 _ Correlation Between Asset Classes: 0.5 Contingent Claim Expiration:12/31/99 Trading Start Date: 6/30/99 Current Trading Period Start Date: 7/1/99 S Current Trading Period End Date: 7/30/99 Next Trading Period Start Date: 8/2/99.
Next Trading Period End Date: . 8/31/99 Current Date: 7/12/99 Last Trading Period End Date: 12/30/99 ~ Aggregate Investment for Current Trading Period: $100 million Trade and Payout Value Units: U.S.-Dollars Table 3.1.6 shows the illustrative distribution of state returns over the defined states for the joint . . ' outcomes based on this information, with the defined states as indicated .
Table 3.1.6-1: Unit Returns for Joint Performance of S&P S00 and JPMGBI
PMGBI

(233,(237,(241,(244,(246,(248,(250,(252,(255,(257,(259,(264,(268, State 0,23337 41 44 46 48 50 52 55 5 59 64 68 ao 0,110224 24 19 41 47 591 79 116178303 352233117 1851 1102,117424 16 11 19 20 23 28137 53 841 142175.799_117 1174,125219 11 61 9 9 9 11 13 18 25 40 44 175 520 1252,129241 19 9 14 13 12 13 15 19 26 39 40 142 581 1334,1359123 9 12 10 9 9 9 11 1 19 18 5 1851 P50 137j~142179 281 11 13 10 9 8 8 12 15 13 37 116 1467,151518515 18 19 1 11 9 9 9 10 12 9 23 591 1515;156431 841 25 26 18 14 12 10 10 11 13 20 47 1614,1720520175 44 40 25 18 13 11 9 9 61 11 19 1720,183411779 17 14284153 37 28123 20 19 11 16 24 ( 1834. 1851117 233352303178 11679 59147 41 19 24 2461 In Table 3.1.6-1, each cell contains the unit returns to the joint state reflected by the row and column entries. For example, the unit return to investments in the state encompassing the joint occurrence of the JPMGBI closing on expiration at 249 and the SP500 closing at 1380 is 88.

Since the correlation between two indices in this example is assumed to be 0.5, the probability both indices will change in the same direction is greater that the probability that both indices will change in opposite directions. In other words, as represented in Table 3.1.6-1, unit returns to investments in states represented in cells in the upper left and lower right of the table -- i.e., where the indices are changing in the same direction -- are lower,.reflecting higher implied probabilities, than unit returns to investments to states represented in cells in the lower left and upper right of Table 3.1.6-1 -- i.e., where the indices are changing in opposite directions.
As in the previous examples and in preferred embodiments, the returns illustrated in Table 3.1.6-1 could be calculated as opening indicative returns at the start of each trading period 10: . based on an estimate of what the closing returns for the trading period are likely to be. These indicative or opening returns can serve as an "anchor point" for commencement of trading in a -group of DBAR contingent claims. Of course, actual trading and trader expectations may induce substantial departures from these indicative values.
Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR contingent claims, 1 S including, for example, digital options, based on multiple underlying events or variables and their inter-relationships. Market participants often have views about the joint outcome of two underlying events or assets. Asset allocation managers, for example, are concerned with the relative~performance of bonds versus equities. .An additional example of multivariate underlying events follows:
20 Joint Performance: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on the joint performance or observation of two different variables. For example, digital options traded in a demand-based market or auction can be based on an underlying event defined as the joint observation of non-farm payrolls and the unemployment rate.
Example 3.1.7: Corporate Bond Credit Risk Groups of DBAR contingent claims can also be constructed on credit events, such as the event that one of the major credit rating agencies (e.g., Standard and Poor's, Moodys) changes the rating for some yr all of a corporation's outstanding securities.
Indicative returns at the outset of trading for a group of DBAR contingent claims oriented to a credit event can readily be constructed from publicly available data from the rating agencies themselves.
For example, Table 3.1.7-1 contains indicative returns for an assumed group of DBAR
contingent claims based on the event that a corporation's Standard and Poor's credit rating for a given security will change over a certain period of time. In this example, states are defined using the Standard and Poor's credit categories, ranging from AAA to D (default). Using the methods of the present invention, the indicative returns are calculated using historical data on the frequency of the S ' occurrence of these defined states. In this example, a transaction fee of 1 % is charged against the aggregate amount invested in the group of DBAR contingent claims, which is assumed to be $100 million.
Table 3.1.7-1: Illustrative Returns for Credit DBAR Contin ent Claims with 1 %
Transaction Fee GSnrent To New Historical Invested in Indicative Return ~ Probabili State ($) to State 0.0016 160,000 617.75 A- AA+ 0.0004 40,000 2474.00 0.0012 120,000 824.00 0.003099 309,900 318.46 A- - A+ 0.010897 1,089,700 ' gg.g5 A- A 0.087574 8,757,400 10.30 A- A- 0.772868 77,286,800 0.28 A- BBB+ 0.068979 6,897,900 13.35 A- BBB 0.03199 3,199,000 29.95 A- BBB- 0.007398 739,800 132.82 A- BB+ 0.002299 229,900 429.62 A- BB 0.004999 499,900 197.04 A- BB- 0.002299 229,900 429.62 ' A- B+ 0.002699 269,900 ~ 365.80 B 0.0004 40,000 2474.00 A- B- 0.0004 40,000 2474.00 A- CCC 1 E-04 10,000 9899.00 A- D : 0.0008 80,000 1236.50 In Table 3.1.7-1, the historical probabilities over the mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive states sum to unity. As demonstrated above in this specification, in preferred embodiments, the transaction fee affects the probability implied for each state from the unit return for that state.
Actual trading is expected almost always to alter illustrative indicative returns based on historical empirical data. This Example 3.1.7 indicates how efficiently groups of DBAR
contingent claims can be constructed for all traders or firms exposed to particular credit risk in order to hedge that risk. For example, in this Example, if a trader has significant exposure to the A- rated bond issue described above, the trader could want to hedge the event corresponding to a downgrade by Standard and Poor's. For example, this trader may be particularly concerned about a downgrade corresponding to an issuer default or "D" rating. The empirical probabilities suggest a payout of approximately $1,237 for each dollar invested in that state. If this trader has $100,000,000 of the corporate issue in his portfolio and a recovery of ratio of 0.3 can be expected in the event of default, then, in order to hedge $70,000,000 of default risk, the trader might invest in the state encompassing a "D" outcome. To hedge the entire amount of the default risk in this example, the amount of the investment in this state should be $70,000,000/$1,237 or $56,589.
This represents approximately 5.66 basis points'of the trader's position size in this bond (i.e., $56,589/$100,000,000 = .00056)] which probably represents a reasonable cost.of credit insurance against default. Actual investments in this group of DBAR contingent claims could alter the return on the "D" event over time and additional insurance might need to be purchased.
Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to offer a wide variety of products related to common measures of credit quality, including Moody's and S&P
ratings, bankruptcy statistics, and recovery rates. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an 1 S underlying event defined as the credit quality of Ford corporate debt as defined by the Standard & Poor's rating agency.
Example 3.1.8: Economic Statistics As financial markets have become more sophisticated, statistical information that measures economic activity has assumed increasing importance as a factor in the investment decisions of market participants. Such economic activity measurements may include, for example, the following U.S. federal government and U.S. and foreign private agency statistics:
~ Employment, National Output, and Income (Non-farm Payrolls, Gross Domestic Product, Personal Income) ~ Orders, Production, and Inventories (Durable Goods Orders, Industrial Production, Manufacturing Inventories) ~ Retail Sales, Housing Starts, Existing Home Sales, Current Account Balance, Employment Cost Index, Consumer Price Index, Federal Funds Target Rate ~ Agricultural statistics released by the U.S.D.A. (crop reports, etc.) ~ The National Association of Purchasing Management (NAPM) survey of manufacturing ~ Standard and Poor's Quarterly Operating Earnings of the S&P 500 ~ The semiconductor book-to-bill ratio published by the Semiconductor Industry Association ~ The Halifax House Price Index used extensively as an authoritative indicator of house price movements in the U.K.

Because the economy is the primary driver of asset performance, every investor that takes a position in equities, foreign exchange, or. fixed income will have exposure to economic forces driving these asset prices, either by accident or design. Accordingly, market participants expend considerable time and resources to assemble data, models and forecasts. In turn, corporations, governments, and financial intermediaries depend heavily on the economic forecasts to allocate resources and to make market projections.
To the extent that economic forecasts are inaccurate, inefficiencies and severe misallocation of resources can result. Unfortunately, traditional derivatives markets fail to provide market participants with a direct mechanism to protect themselves against the adverse consequences of falling demand or rising input prices on a macroeconomic level. Demand-based markets or auctions for economic products, however, provide market participants with a market price for the risk that a particular measure of economic activity will vary from expectations and a tool to. properly hedge the risk. The market participants can trade in a market or an auction where the event of economic significance is an underlying measure of economic activity (e.g., the VIX index as calculated by the CBOE) or a measured parameter related to the underlying event (e.g., an implied volatility or standard deviation of the VIX index).
For example, traders often hedge inflation risk by trading in bond futures or, where they exist, inflation-protected floating rate bonds. A group of_DBAR contingent claims can readily be constructed to allow traders to express expectations about the distribution of uncertain economic - statistics measuring, for example, the rate of inflation or other relevant variables. The following information describes such a group of claims:
Economic Statistic: United States Non-Farm Payrolls Announcement Date: 5/31/99 Last Announcement Date: 4/30/99 Expiration: Announcement Date, 5/31/99 Trading Start Date: 5/1/99 Current Trading Period Start Date: S/10/99 Current Trading Period End Date: 5/14/99 Current Date: 5/11/99 Last Announcement: 128,156 ('000) Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics Consensus Estimate: 130,000 (+1.2 %) Aggregate Amount Invested in Current Period: $100 million Transaction Fee: 2.0% of Aggregate Traded amount Using methods and systems of the present invention, states can be defined and indicative returns can be constructed from, for example, consensus estimates among economists for this index. These estimates can be expressed in absolute values or, as illustrated, in Table 3.1.8-1 in percentage changes from the last observation as follows:
Table 3.1.8-1 Illustrative. Returns For Non-Farm Payrolls Release with 2% Transaction Fee Chg. In Investment State ReturnsImplied State Index in State Probability State ('000) [-100,-5] 100 979 0.001 , (-5; 3] 200 489 0.002 (-3; 1 ] 400 244 0.004 (-1; .5]. 500 195 0.005 (-.S,O] 1000 97 0.01 (0,.5] 2000 48 0.02 (.5,.7] 3000 31.66667 0.03 (.7,.8] 4000 23.5 0.04 (.8,.9] 5000 18.6 0.05 -(.9,1.0] 10000 8.8 0.1 (1.0,1.1] 14000 6 0.14 _ , (1.1,1.2] 22000 3.454545 0.22 (1.2,1.25] 18000 4.444444 0.18 (1.25,1.3] 9000 9.888889 0.09 (1.3,1.35) 6000 15.33333 0.06 (1.35,1.40]3000 31.66667 0.03 (1.40,1.45]200 489 0.002 (1.45,1.5] 600 162.3333 0.006 (1.5,1.6] 400 244 0.004 (1.6,1.7] 100 979 0.001 (1.7,1.8] 80 1224 0.0008 ( 1.8,1.9] 59 1660.017 0.00059 ( 1.9,2.0] 59 1660.017 0.00059 (2.0,2.1] 59 1660.017 0.00059 (2.1,2.2) 59 1660.017 0.00059 (2.2,2.4] . 59 1660.017 0.00059 (2.4,2.6] 59 1660.017 0.00059 (2.6,3.0] 59 1660.017 0.00059 (3.0, do] 7 13999 0 00007 I

_97_ As in examples, actual trading prior to the trading end date would be expected to adjust returns according to the amounts invested in each state and the total amount invested for all the states.
Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to offer a wide variety of products S related to commonly observed indices and statistics related to economic activity and released or published by governments, and by domestic, foreign and international government or private companies, institutions, agencies or other entities. These may include a large number of statistics that measure the performance of the economy, such as employment, national income, inventories, consumer spending,, etc., in addition to measures of real property and other economic activity.
An additional example follows:
Private Economic Indices & Statistics: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on economic statistics released or published by private sources. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the NAPM
Index published by the National Association of Purchasing Managers.
Alternative private indices might also include measures of real property. For example, DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, can be based on an underlying event defined as the level of the Halifax House Price Index at year-end, 2001.
In addition to the general advantages of the demand-based trading system, demand-based products on economic statistics will provide the following new opportunities for trading and risk management:
(1) Insuring against the event risk component of assetprice movements.
Statistical releases can often cause extreme short-term price movements in the fixed income and equity markets.
Many market participants have strong views on particular economic reports, and try to capitalize on such views by taking positions in the bond or equity markets.
Demand-based markets or auctions on economic statistics provide participants with a means of taking a direct view on economic variables, rather than the indirect approach employed currently.
(2) Risk management for real economic activity. State governments, municipalities, insurance companies, and corporations may all have a strong interest in a particular measure of real economic activity. For example, the Department of Energy publishes the Electric Power Monthly which provides electricity statistics at the State, Census division, and U.S. levels for _9g_ net generation, fossil fuel consumption and stocks, quantity and quality of fossil fuels, cost of fossil fuels, electricity retail sales, associated revenue, and average revenue. Demand-based markets or auctions based on one or more of these energy benchmarks can serve as invaluable risk management mechanisms for corporations and governments seeking to manage the increasingly uncertain outlook for electric power.
(3) Sector-specific risk mana eg ment. The Health Care CPI (Consumer Price Index) published by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics tracks the CPI of medical care on a monthly basis in the CPI Detailed Report. A demand-based market or auction on this statistic would have broad applicability for insurance companies; drug companies, hospitals, and many other participants in the health care industry. Similarly, the semiconductor book-to-bill ratio serves as a direct measure of activity in the semiconductor equipment manufacturing industry. The ratio reports-both shipments and new bookings with a short time lag, and hence is a useful measure of supply and demand balance in the semiconductor industry. Not only would manufacturers and consumers of semiconductors have a direct financial interest, but the 15' ratio's status as a bellwether of the general technology market would invite participation from financial market participants as well.
Example 3.1.9: Corporate Events Corporate actions and announcements are further examples of events of economic significance which are usually unhedgable or uninsurable in traditional markets but which can be effectively structured into groups of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention.
In recent years, corporate earnings expectations, which are typically announced on a quarterly basis for publicly traded companies, have assumed increasing importance as more companies forego dividends to reinvest in continuing operations. Without dividends, the present value of an equity becomes entirely dependent on revenues and earnings streams that extend well into the future, causing the equity itself to take on the characteristics of an option. As expectations of future cash flows change, the impact on pricing can be dramatic, causing stock prices in many cases to exhibit option=like behavior.
Traditionally, market participants expend considerable time and resources to assemble data, models and forecasts. To the extent that forecasts are inaccurate, inefficiencies and severe misallocation of resources can result. Unfortunately, traditional derivatives markets fail to provide market participants with a direct mechanism to manage the unsystematic risks of equity ownership. Demand-based markets or auctions for corporate earnings and revenues, however, provide market participants with a concrete price for the risk that earnings and revenues may vary from expectations and permit them to insure or hedge or speculate on the risk.
Many data services, such as IBES and FirstCall, currently publish estimates by analysts and a consensus estimate in advance of quarterly earnings announcements. Such estimates can form the basis for indicative opening returns at the commencement of trading in a demand-based market or auction as illustrated below. For this example, a transaction fee of zero is assumed.
Underlying security: IBM
Earnings Announcement Date: 7/21/99 Consensus Estimate: .879/share Expiration: Announcement, 7/21/99 First. Trading Period Start Date: 4/19/99 First Trading Period End Date 5/19/99 Current Trading Period Start Date: 7/6/99 15. . Current Trading Period End Date: 7/9/99 Next Trading Period Start Date: 7/9/99 Next Trading Period End Date: 7/16/99 Total Amount Invested in Current Trading Period: $100 million Table 3.1.9-1: Illustrative Returns For IBM Earnings Announcement Earnings Invested in Unit ReturnsImplied State Probability StateO State 000 $

70 1,427.57 0.0007 (.5,.6] 360 276.78 0.0036 . .. (.6, .65]730 135.99 0.0073 (.65,.7] 1450 67.97 0.0145 {.7,.74] 2180 44.87 0.0218 (.74,.78]3630 26.55 0.0363 (-78'"8] 4360 21.94 0.0436 (.8,.82] 5820 16.18 0.0582 (.82,.84]7270 12:76 0.0727 (.84,.86]8720 10.47 0.0872 ('86''87]10900 8.17 0.109 ('87''88]18170 4.50 0.1817 ('88,'89]8720 10.47 0.0872 (.89,.9] 7270 12.76 0.0727 (.9,.91 5090 18.65 0.0509 ]

(.91,.92]3630 26.55 0.0363 (.92,.93]2910 33.36 0.0291 - g~0 (.93,.95)2180 44.87 0.0218 (.95,.97]1450 67.97 0.0145 (.97,.99]1310 75.34 0.0131 (.99,1.1)1160 85.21 0.0116 . ' (1.1,1.3]1020 97.04 0.0102 (1.3,1.5]730 135.99 0.0073 (1.5,1.7]360 276.78 0.0036 (1.7,1.9)220 453.55 0.0022 .

(1.9,2.1]150 665.67 0.0015 (2.1,2.3]70 1,427.57 0.0007 (2.3,2.5]40 2,499.00 0.0004 (2.5, 30 3,332.33 0.0003 ao) Consistent with the consensus estimate, the state with the largest investment encompasses the range (.87, .88].
Table 3.1.9-2: Illustrative Returns for Microso$ Earnings Announcement ~ 1 !~ n n ~' I I ~ 1l I ~~
~t i'~, 1 ~ I~,~I
trike id I~~ olume trikeBid olume ~ Payout Offer Payout Offer <40 0.95250.95751.04714,100,000 <40 0.04250.047522.2222193,100 <41, 0.90250.90751.10501,000,000 <41 0.09250.097510.5263105,500 <42 0.83730.84231.19089,700 <42 0.15770.16276.2422 -<43 0.74750.75251.33333,596,700 <43 0.24750.25254.0000 1;200,000 <44 0.622 0.627 1.60132,000,000 <44 0.37300.37802.6631 1,202,500 <45 0.49750.50252.00006,000,000 <45 0.49750.50252.0000 6,000,000 <46 0.367503725 2.70272,500,000 <46 0.62750.63251.5873 4,256,600 <47 0.21750.22254.54551,000,000 <47 0.77750.78251.2821 3,545,700 <48 0.12450.12957.8740800,000 <48 0.87050.87551.1455 5,500,000 <49 0.086 0.091 11.2994- <49 0.90900.91401.0971 DSO 0.04750.052520.000194,700 <50 0.94750.95251.0526 3,700,000 - fi~1 -The table above provides a sample distribution of trades that might be made for an April
23 auction period for Microsoft Q4 corporate earnings (June 2001), due to be released on July 16, 2001.
For example, at 29 times trailing earnings and 28 times consensus 2002 earnings, Microsoft is experiencing single digit profit growth and is the object of uncertainty with respect to sales of Microsoft Office, adoption rates of Windows 2000, and the .Net initiative. In the sample demand-based market or auction based on earnings expectations depicted above, a market participant can engage, for example, in the following trading tactics and strategies with respect to DBAR digital options.
~ A fund manager wishing to avoid market risk at the current time but who still wants _ ." exposure to Microsoft can buy the .43 Earnings per Share Call (consensus currently .44-45) with reasonable confidence that reported earnings will be 43 cents or higher. Should Microsoft report earnings as expected, the trader earns approximately 33% on invested 15. . demand=based trading digital option premium (i.e., 1 / option price of .7525).
Conversely, should Microsoft report earnings below 43 cents, the invested premium would be lost, but the consequences for Microsoft's stock price would likely be dramatic.
~ A more aggressive strategy would involve selling or underweighting Microsoft stock, while purchasing a string of digital options on higher than expected EPS
growth. In this case, the trader expects a multiple contraction to occur over the short to medium term, as the valuation becomes unsustainable. Using the market for DBAR contingent claims on earnings depicted above, a trader with a $5 million notional exposure to Microsoft can buy a string of digital call options, as follows:
Strike Premium Price Net Payout .46 $ 37,000 0.3725 $ 62,329 .47 22,000 0.2225 139,205 .48 6,350 0.1295 181,890 .49 4,425 0.0910 226,091 .50 0 0.0525 226,091 The payouts displayed immediately above are net of premium investment.
Premiums invested are based on the trader's assessment of likely stock price (and price multiple) reaction to a possible earnings surprise. Similar trades in digital options on earnings would be made in successive quarters, resulting in a string of options on higher ,_.
than expected earnings growth, to protect against an upward shift in the earnings expectation curve, as shown in FIG. 21.
The total cost, for this quarter, amounts to $69,775, just above a single quarter's interest income on the notional $5,000,000, invested at 5%.
A trader.with a view on a range of earnings expectations for the quarter can profit from a spread strategy over the distribution. By purchasing the .42 call and selling the .46 call, the trader can construct a digital option spread priced at: .8423 - .3675 =
.4748. This spread would, consequently, pay out: 1/.4748 = 2.106, for every dollar invested.
Many trades can be constructed using demand-based trading for DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on corporate earnings.
The examples showmhere are intended to be representative, not definitive. Moreover, demand-based trading products can be based on corporate accounting measures, including a wide variety of generally , accepted accounting information from corporate balance sheets, income statements, and other measures of cash flow, such as earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization (EBTfDA). The following examples provide a fimther representative sampling:
Revenues: Demand-based markets or auctions for DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options can be based on a measure or parameter related to Cisco revenues, such as the gross revenues reported by the Cisco Corporation. The underlying event for these claims is the quarterly or annual gross revenue figure for Cisco as calculated and released to the public by the reporting company.
EBITDA (EarnlriQS Before Interest Taxes Depreciation Amortization): Demand-based markets or auctions for DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options can be based on a measure or parameter related to AOL EBITDA, such as the EBITDA
figure reported by AOL that is used to provide a measure of operating earnings. The underlying event for these claims is the quarterly or annual EBITDA figure for AOL as calculated and released to the public by the reporting company.
In addition to the general advantages of the demand-based trading system, products based on corporate earnings and revenues may provide the following new opportunities for trading and risk management: .
(1) Trading the price of a stock relative to its earnings. Traders can use a market for earnings to create a "Multiple Trade," in which a stock would be sold (or 'not owned') and a string of DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on quarterly earnings can be used as a hedge or insurance for stock believed to be overpriced.
Market expectations for a company's earnings may be faulty, and may threaten the stability of a stock price, post announcement. Corporate announcements that reduce expectation for earnings and earnings growth highlight the consequences for high-multiple growth stocks that fail to meet expectations. For example, an equity investment manager might decide to underweight a high-multiple stock against a benchmark, and replace it with a series of DBAR
digital options corresponding to a projected profile for earnings growth. The manager can compare the cost of this strategy with the risk of owning the underlying security, based on the company's PE
ratio or some other metric chosen by the fund manager. Conversely, an investor who expects a multiple expansion for a given stock would purchase demand-based trading digital put options on earnings, retaining the stock for a multiple expansion while protecting against a shortfall in reported earnings.
(2) Insuring against an earnings shortfall while maintaining a stock position during a period when eguity options are deemed too expensive. While DBAR contingent claims, including, for.example, digital options, based on earnings are not designed to hedge stock prices, they can provide a cost-effective means to mitigate the risk of equity ownership over longer term horizons. For example, periodically, three-month stock options that are slightly out-of the-money can command premiums of 10% or more. The ability to insure against possible earnings or revenue shortfalls one quarter or more in the future via purchases of DBAR
digital options may represent an attractive alternative to conventional hedge strategies for equity price risks.
(3) Insuring against an earnings shortfall that may trigger credit down ades.
Fixed income managers worried about potential exposure to credit downgrades from reduced corporate earnings can use DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, to protect _10c_ against earnings shortfalls that would impact EBITDA and prompt declines in corporate bond prices. Conventional fixed income and convertible bond managers can protect against equity exposures without a short sale of the corresponding equity shares.
(4) Obtaining low-risk, incremental returns. Market participants can use deep-in-the-money DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on earnings as a source of low-risk, uncorrelated returns.
Example 3.1.10: Real Assets Another advantage of the methods and systems of the present invention is the ability to structure liquid claims on illiquid underlying assets such a real estate. As previously discussed, traditional derivatives markets customarily use a liquid underlying market in order to fimction properly. With a group of DBAR contingent claims all that is usually required is a real-world, observable event of economic significance. For eXample, the creation of contingent claims tied to real assets has been attempted at some financial institutions over the last several years: These efforts have not been credited with an appreciable impact, apparently because of the primary liquidity constraints inherent in the underlying real assets.
A group of DBAR contingent claims according .to the present invention can be constructed based on an observable event related to real estate. The relevant information for an illustrative group of such claims is as follows:
Deal Asset Index: Colliers ABR Manhattan Office Rent Rates Bloomberg Ticker: COLA,MANR

Update Frequency: Monthly Source: Colliers ABR, Inc.

Announcement Date: 7/31/99 Last Announcement Date:

Last Index Value : $45.39/sq. ft.
Consensus Estimate: $45.50 Expiration: Announcement 7/31/99 Current Trading Period Start: 6/30/99 Current Trading Period End: 7/7/99 Next Trading Period Start 7/7/99 Next Trading Period End 7/14/99 For reasons of brevity, defined states and opening indicative or illustrative returns resulting from amounts invested in the various states for this example are not shown, but can be calculated or will emerge from actual trader investments according to the methods of the present invention as illustrated in Examples 3.1.1-3.1.9.
Demand-based markets. or auctions can be structured to offer a wide variety of products related to real assets, such as real estate, bandwidth, wireless spectrum capacity, or computer memory. An additional example follows:
Computer MemorX: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on computer memory components. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the 64Mb (8x8) PC 133 DRAM memory chip prices and on the rolling 90-day average of Dynamic Random Access Memory DRAM.prices as reported each Friday by ICIS-LOR, a commodity price monitoring group based in London.
1 S - . Example 3.1.11: Ener~y Supply Chain A group of DBAR contingent claims can also be constructed using the methods and systems of the present invention to provide hedging vehicles on non-tradable quantities of great economic significance within the supply chaiwof a given industry. An example of such an application is the number of oil rigs currently deployed in domestic U.S. oil production. The rig count tends to be a slowly adjusting quantity that is sensitive to energy prices. Thus, appropriately structured groups of DBAR contingent claims based on rig counts could enable suppliers, producers and drillers to hedge exposure to sudden changes in energy prices and could provide a valuable risk-sharing device.
For example, a group of DBAR contingent claims depending on the rig count could be constructed according to the present invention using the following information (e.g., data source, termination criteria, etc).
Asset Index: Baker Hughes Rig Count U.S. Total Bloomberg Ticker: BAKETOT
Frequency: Weekly Source: Baker Hughes, Inc.
Announcement Date: 7/16/99 Last Announcement Date: 7/9/99 Expiration Date: 7/16/99 Trading Start Date: 7/9/99 Trading End Date: 7/15/99 Last: 570 Consensus Estimate: 580 For reasons-of brevity, defined states and opening indicative or illustrative returns resulting from amounts invested in the various states for this example are not shown, but can be readily calculated or will emerge from actual trader investments according to the methods of the present invention, as illustrated in Examples 3.1.1-3.1.9. A variety of embodiments of DBAR
contingent claims, including for example, digital options, can be based on an underlying event defined as the Baker Hughes Rig Count observed on a semi-annual basis.
Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to offer a wide variety of products related to power and emissions, including electricity prices, loads, degree-days, water supply, and pollution credits. The following examples provide a further representative sampling:
Electricity Prices: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on the price of electricity at various points on the electricity grid. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the weekly average price of electricity in kilowatt-hours at the New York Independent System Operator (NYISO).
Transmission Load: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on the actual load (power demand) experienced.for a particular power pool, allowing participants to trade volume, in addition to price. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the weekly total load demand experienced by Pennsylvania-~ New Jersey-Maryland Interconnect (PJM Western Hub).
Water: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on water supply. Water measures are useful to a broad variety of constituents, including power companies, agricultural producers, and municipalities. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the cumulative precipitation observed at weather stations maintained by the National Weather Service in the Northwest catchment area, including Washington, Idaho, Montana, and Wyoming.
-1~7-Emission Allowances: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on emission allowances for various pollutants. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as price of Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) , sulfur dioxide allowances at the annual market or auction administered by the Chicago Board of Trade.
Example 3.1.12: Mortgage Prepayment Risk Real estate mortgages comprise an extremely large fixed income asset class with hundreds of billions in market capitalization. Market participants generally understand that these mortgage-backed securities are subject to interest rate risk and the risk that borrowers may exercise their options to refinance their mortgages or otherwise "prepay"
their existing mortgage loans. The owner of a mortgage security, therefore, bears the risk of being "called" out of its position when mortgage interest rate levels decline.
1 S Market participants expend considerable time and resources assembling econometric models and synthesizing various data populations in order to generate prepayment projections.
To the extent that economic forecasts are inaccurate, inefficiencies and severe misallocation of resources can result. Unfortunately, traditional derivatives markets fail to provide market participants with a direct mechanism to protect themselves against a homeowner's exercise of its prepayment option. Demand-based markets or auctions for mortgage prepayment products, however, provide market participants with a concrete price for prepayment risk.
Groups of DBAR contingent claims can be structured according to the present invention, for example, based on the following information:
Asset Index: FNMA Conventional 30 year One-Month Historical Aggregate Prepayments Coupon: 6.5%
Frequency: Monthly Source: ~ Bloomberg Announcement Date: 8/1/99 Last Announcement Date: 7/1/99 Expiration: Announcement Date, 8/1/99 Current Trading Period Start Date: 7/1/99 Current Trading Period End Date: 7/9/99 Last: 303 Public Securities Association Prepayment Speed ("PSA") Consensus Estimate: 310 PSA
For reasons of brevity, defined states and opening indicative or illustrative returns resulting from amounts invested in the various states for this example are not shown, but can be readily calculated or will emerge from actual trader investments according to the methods of the present invention, as illustrated in Examples 3.1.1-3.1.9.
In addition to the general advantages of the demand-based trading system, products on '. mortgage prepayments may provide the following exemplary new opportunities for trading and .
risk management:
(1) Asset-specific applications. In the simplest form, the owner of a prepayable mortgage=backed security carries, by definition, a series of short option positions embedded in the asset; whereas a DBAR contingent claim, including, for example, a digital option, based on mortgage prepayments would constitute a long option .position. A
security owner would have the opportunity to compare the digital option's expected return with the prospective loss of principal, correlate the offsetting options, and invest accordingly. While this tactic would not eliminate reinvestment risks, per. se, it would generate incremental investment returns that would reduce the security owner's embedded liabilities with respect to short option positions.
(2) Portfolio applications. Certainly, a similar strategy could be applied on an expanded basis to a portfolio of mortgage-backed securities, or a portfolio of whole mortgage loans.
(3) Enhancements to specific~ools. Certain pools of seasoned mortgage loans exhibit consistent prepayment patterns, based upon comprehensible factors - origination period, underwriting standards, borrower circumstances, geographic phenomena, etc. Because of homogeneous prepayment performance, mortgage market participants can obtain greater confidence with respect to the accuracy of predictions for prepayments in these pools, than in the case of pools of heterogeneous, newly originated loans that lack a prepayment history.
Market conventions tend to assign lower volatility estimates to the correlation of prepayment changes in seasoned pools for given interest rate changes, than in the case of newer pools. A
relatively consistent prepayment pattern for seasoned mortgage loan pools would heighten the certainty of correctly anticipating future prepayments, which would heighten the likelihood of consistent success in trading in DBAR contingent claims such as, for example, digital options, based on respective mortgage prepayments. Such digital option investments, combined with seasoned pools, would tend to enhance annuity-like cash profiles, and reduce investment risks.
(4) Prepayment puts plus discount MBS. Discount mortgage-backed securities tend to enjoy two-fold benefits as interest rates decline in the form of positive price changes and increases in prepayment speeds. Converse penalties apply in events of increases in interest rates, where a discount MBS suffers from adverse price change, and a decline in prepayment income. A
discount MBS owner could offset diminished prepayment income by investing in DBAR
contingent claims, such as, for example, digital put options, or digital put option spreads on prepayments. An analogous strategy would apply to principal-only mortgage-backed securities.
(5) Prepayment calls plus premium MBS. An expectation of interest rate declines that accelerate prepayment activity for premium mortgage-backed securities would motivate a premium bond-holder to purchase DBAR contingent claims, such as, for example, digital call options, based on mortgage prepayments to offset losses attributable to unwelcome paydowns. The analogue would also apply to interest-only mortgage-backed securities.
(6) Convexity additions. An investment in a DBAR contingent claim, such as, for example, a digital option, based on mortgage prepayments should effectively add convexity to an interest rate sensitive investment. According to this reasoning, dollar-weighted purchases of a demand-based market or auction on mortgage prepayments would tend to offset the negative convexity exhibited by mortgage-backed securities. It is likely.that expert participants in the mortgage marketplace will analyze and test, and ultimately harvest, the fruitful opportunities for combinations of DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on mortgage prepayments with mortgage-backed securities and derivatives.
Example 3.1.13: Insurance Industry Loss Warranty ("ILW"j The cumulative impact of catastrophic and non-catastrophic insurance losses over the past two years has reduced the capital available in the retrocession market (i.e.
reinsurance for reinsurance companies) and pushed up insurance and reinsurance rates for property catastrophe coverage. Because large reinsurance companies operate global businesses with global exposures, - gI0-severe losses from catastrophes in one country tend to drive up insurance and reinsurance rates for unrelated perils in other countries simply due to capital constraints.
As capital becomes scarce and insurance rates increase, market participants usually access the capital markets by purchasing catastrophic bonds (CAT bonds) issued by special purpose reinsurance companies. The capital markets can absorb the risk of loss associated with larger disasters, whereas a single insurer or even a group of insurers cannot, because the risk is spread across many more market participants.
Unlike traditional capital markets that generally exhibit a natural two-way order flow, insurance.markets typically exhibit one-way demand generated by participants desiring 10' .-. ' protection from adverse outcomes. Because demand-based trading products do not require:an underlying source of supply, such products provide an attractive alternative for access to capital.
Groups of DBAR contingent claims can be structured using the system and methods of . ' the present invention to provide insurance and reinsurance facilities for property and casualty, life, health and other traditional lines of insurance. The following information provides information to structure a group of DBAR contingent claims related .to large property losses from hurricane damage:
Event: PCS Eastern Excess $5 billion Index Source: Property Claim Services (PCS) Frequency: Monthly ., Announcement Date: 10/1/99 ' Last Announcement Date: 7/1/99 Last Index Value: No events Consensus Estimate: $1 billion (claims excess of $5 billion) Expiration: Announcement Date, 10/1/99 Trading Period Start Date: 7/1/99 Trading Period End Date: 9/30/99 For reasons of brevity, defined states and opening indicative or illustrative returns resulting from amounts invested in the various states for this example are not shown, but can be readily calculated or will emerge from actual trader investments according to the methods of the present invention, as illustrated in Examples 3.1.1-3.1.9.
- lgl -In preferred embodiments of groups of DBAR contingent claims related to property-casualty catastrophe losses, the frequency of claims and the distributions of the severity of losses ate assumed and convolutions are performed in order to post indicative returns over the distribution of defined states. This can be done, for example, using compound frequency-severity models, such as the Poisson-Pareto model, familiar to those of skill in the art, which predict; with greater probability than a normal distribution, when losses will be extreme. As indicated previously, in preferred embodiments market activity is expected to alter the posted indicative returns, which serve as informative levels at the commencement of trading.
Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to offer a wide variety of products related to insurance industry loss warranties and other insurable risks, including property and non-property catastrophe, mortality rates, mass torts, etc. An additional example follows:
Property Catastrophe: Demand-based markets or auctions can be based on the outcome of natural catastrophes, including earthquake, fire, atmospheric peril, and flooding, etc.
Underlying events can be based on hazard parameters. For example, DBAR
contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the cumulative losses sustained in California as the result of earthquake damage in the year 2002, as calculated by the Property Claims Service (PCS).
In addition to the general advantages of the demand-based trading system, products on catastrophe risk will provide the following new opportunities for trading and risk management:
(1) Greater transaction efficiency and precision. A demand-based trading catastrophe risk product, such as, for example, a DBAR digital option, allows participants to buy or sell a precise notional quantity of desired risk, at any point along a catastrophe risk probability curve, with a limit price for the risk. A series of loss triggers can be created for catastrophic events that offer greater flexibility and customization for insurance transactions, in addition to indicative pricing for all trigger levels. Segments of risk coverage can be traded with ease and precision. Participants in demand-based trading catastrophe risk products gain the ability to adjust risk protection or exposure to a desired level. For example, a reinsurance company may wish to purchase protection at the tail of a distribution, for unlikely but extremely catastrophic losses, while writing insurance in other parts of the distribution where returns may appear attractive.
(2) Credit quality. Claims-paying ability of an insurer or reinsurer represents an important concern for many market participants. Participants in a demand-based market or auction do -lb2-not depend on the credit quality of an individual insurance or reinsurance company. A
demand-based market or auction is by nature self fiuiding, meaning that catastrophic losses in other product or geographic areas will not impair the ability of a demand-based trading catastrophe risk product to make capital distributions.
Example 3.1.14: Conditional Events As discussed above, advantage of the systems and methods of the present invention is the ability to construct groups of DBAR contingent claims related to events of economic significance for which there is great interest in insurance and hedging, but which are not readily hedged or insured in traditional capital and insurance markets. Another example of such an event is. one that occurs only when some related event has previously occurred. For purposes of illustration, these two events may be denoted A and B.
q~A~ B\ - q(A n B) q(B) where q denotes the probability of a state, q~A) B~ represents the conditional probability of state A given the prior occurrence of state and B, and q(A n B) represents the occurrence of both states A and B.
For example, a group of DBAR contingent claims may be constructed to combine elements of "key person" insurance and the performance of the stock price of the company managed by the key person. Many firms are managed by people whom capital markets perceive as indispensable or particularly important, such as Warren Buffett of Berkshire Hathaway. The holders of Berkshire Hathaway stock have no ready way of insuring against the sudden change in management of Berkshire, either due to a corporate action such as a takeover or to the death or disability of Warren Buffett. A group of conditional DBAR contingent claims can be constructed according to the present invention where the defined states reflect the stock price of Berkshire Hathaway conditional on Warren Buffet's leaving the firm's management. Other conditional DBAR contingent claims that could attract significant amounts for investment can be constructed using the methods and systems of the present invenrion, as apparent to one of skill in the art.
Example 3.1.15: Securitization Using a DBAR Continent Claim Mechanism The systems and methods of the present invention can also be adapted by a financial intermediary or issuer for the issuance of securities such as bonds, common or preferred stock, or -i13-other types of financial instruments. The process of creating new opportunities for hedging underlying events through the creation of new securities is known as "securitization," and is also discussed in an embodiment presented in Section 10. Well-known examples of securitization include the mortgage and asset-backed securities markets, in which portfolios of financial risk are aggregated and then recombined into new sources of financial risk. The systems and methods of the present invention can be used within the securitization process by creating securities, or portfolios of securities, whose risk, in whole or part, is tied to an associated or embedded group of DBAR contingent claims. In a preferred embodiment, a group of DBAR
contingent claims is associated with a security much like options are currently associated with bonds in order to create . . callable and putable bonds in the traditional markets.
This example illustrates how a group of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention can be tied to the issuance of a security in order to share risk associated with an identified future event among the security holders. In this example, the security is a fixed income bond with an embedded group of DBAR contingent claims whose value depends on the possible values for hurncane losses over some time period for some geographic region.
Issuer: Tokyo Fire and Marine Underwriter: Goldman Sachs DBAR Event: Total Losses on a Saffir-Simpson Category 4 Hurricane Geographic: Property Claims Services Eastern North America Date: 7/1/99-11/1/99 Size of Issue: 500 million USD.
Issue Date: 6/1/99 DBAR Trading Period: 6/1/99-7/1/99 In this example, the underwriter Goldman Sachs issues the bond, and holders of the issued bond put bond principal at risk over the entire distribution of amounts of Category 4 losses for the event. Ranges of possible losses comprise the defined states for the embedded group of DBAR contingent claims. In a preferred embodiment, the underwriter is responsible for updating the returns to investments in the various states, monitoring credit risk, and clearing and settling, and validating the amount of the losses. When the event is determined and uncertainty is resolved, Goldman is "put" or collects the bond principal at risk from the unsuccessful investments and allocates these amounts to the successful investments. The mechanism in this illustration thus includes:
-g14'~_ (1) An underwriter or intermediary which implements the mechanism, and (2) A group of DBAR contingent claims directly tied to a security or issue (such as the catastrophe bond above).
For reasons of brevity, defined states and opening indicative or illustrative returns resulting from amounts invested in the various states for this example are not shown, but can be ieadily calculated or will emerge from actual trader investments according to the methods of the present invention, as illustrated in Examples 3.1.1-3.1.9.
Example 3.1.16: Exotic Derivatives The securities and derivatives communities frequently use the tenor."exotic derivatives" to refer to derivatives whose values are linked to a security, asset, financial product or source of financial risk in a more complicated fashion than traditional derivatives such as futures, call options, and convertible bonds. Examples of exotic derivatives include American options, Asian options, barrier options, Bermudan options, choosey and compound options, binary or digital options, lookback options, automatic and flexible caps and floors, and shout options.
Many types of exotic options are currently traded. For example, barner options are rights to purchase an underlying financial product, such as a quantity of foreign currency, for a specified rate or price, but only if, for example, the underlying exchange rate crosses or does not cross one or more defined rates or "barners." For example, a dollar call/yen put on the dollar/yen exchange rate, expiring in three months with strike price 110 and "knock-out"
barrier of 105, entitles the holder to purchase a quantity of dollars at 110 yen per dollar, but only if the exchange rate did not fall below 105 at any point during the three month duration of the option. Another example of a commonly traded exotic derivative, an Asian option, depends on the average value of the underlying security over some time period. Thus, a class of exotic derivatives is commonly referred to as "path-dependent" derivatives, such as barrier and Asian options, since their values depend not only on the value of the underlying financial product at a given date, but on a history of the value or state of the underlying financial product.
The properties and features of exotic derivatives are often so complex so as to present a significant source of "model risk" or the risk that the tools, or the assumptions upon which they are based, will lead to significant errors in pricing and hedging.
Accordingly, derivatives traders and risk managers often employ sophisticated analytical tools to trade, hedge, and manage the risk of exotic derivatives.
-lll5-One of the advantages of the systems and methods of the present invention is the ability to construct groups of DBAR contingent claims with exotic features that are more manageable and transparent than traditional exotic derivatives. For example, a trader might be interested in the earliest time the yen/dollar exchange rate crosses 95 over the next three months. A traditional barrier option, or portfolio of such exotic options, might suffice to approximate the source of risk of interest to this trader. A group of DBAR contingent claims, in contrast, can be constructed to isolate this risk and present relatively transparent opportunities for hedging. A risk to be isolated is the distribution of possible outcomes for what barrier derivatives traders term the "first passage time," or, in this example, the first time that the,yen/dollar exchange rate crosses 95 over the next three months.
The following illustration shows how such a group of DBAR contingent claims can be constructed to address this risk. In this example, it is assumed that all traders in the group of claims agree that the underlying exchange rate is lognormally distributed.
This group of claims illustrates how traders would invest in states and thus express opinions regarding whether and when the forward yen/dollar exchange rate will cross a given barrier over the next 3 months:
Underlying Risk: Japanese/LJ:S: Dollar Yen Exchange Rate Current Date: 9/15/99 .
Expiration: Forward Rate First Passage Time, as defined, between 9/16/99 to 12/16/99 . Trading Start Date: 9/15/99 Trading End Date: 9/16/99 Barrier: 95 Spot JPY/USD: 104.68 Forward JPY/LTSD 103.268 Assumed (Illustrative) Market Volatility: 20% annualized Aggregate Traded Amount: 10 million USD
-lg6-Table 3.1.16-1: First Passage Time for Yen/Dollar 12/16/99 Forward Exchan eg Rate Time in Year crested in State Return Per Unit if Fractions '000 State Occurs (0,.005] 229.7379 42.52786 (.005, .0l] 848.9024 10.77992 (.0i, .015] 813.8007 11.28802 (.015, .02] 663.2165 14.07803 (.02, .025] 536.3282 17.6453 (.025.03] 440.5172 21.70059 ,(.03, ..035] 368.4647 26.13964 .

(.035, .04] 313.3813 30.91 ('W '~5] 270.4207 35.97942 (.045,.05] . 236.2651 41.32534 (.05,.075] 850.2595 10.76112 (.075,.1 ] 540.0654. 17.51627 (.1;.125] 381.3604 25.22191 (.125,.15] 287.6032 33.77013 (.15,.175] 226.8385 43.08423 (:175,.2j 184.8238 53.10558 (.2,.225] 154.3511 63.78734 (.225,.25] 131.4217 75.09094 Did Not Hit 2522.242 2.964727 Barrier As with other examples, and in preferred embodiments, actual trading will likely generate traded.amounts and therefore returns that depart from the assumptions used to compute the illustrative returns for each state.
In addition to the straightforward multivariate events outlined above, demand-based -markets or auctions can be used to create and trade digital options (as described in Sections 6 and 7) on calculated underlying events (including the events described in this Section 3), similar to those found in exotic derivatives. Many exotic derivatives are based on path-dependent outcomes such as the average of an underlying event over time, price thresholds, a multiple of the underlying, or some sort of time constraint. An additional example follows:
Path Dependent: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
.contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, on an underlying event that is the subject of a calculation. For example, digital options traded in a demand-based 1 S market or auction could be based on an underlying event defined as the average price of yen/dollar exchange rate for the last quarter of 2001.

Example 3.1.17: Hed in~Markets for Real Goods, Commodities and Services Investment and capital budgeting choices faced by firms typically involve inherent econorilic risk (e.g., future demand for semiconductors), large capital investments (e.g., semiconductor fabrication capacity) and timing (e.g., a decision to invest in a plant now, or defer for some period of time). Many economists who study such decisions under uncertainty have recognized that such choices involve what they term "real options." This characterization indicates that the choice to invest now or to defer an investment in goods or services or a plant, for example, in the face of changing uncerEainty and information, frequently entails risks similar to those encountered by traders who have invested in options which provide the opportunity to buy or sell an underlying asset in the capital markets. Many economists and investors recognize he importance of real options in capital budgeting decisions and of setting up markets to better manage their uncertainty and value. Natural resource and extractive industries, such as petroleum exploration and production, as well as industries requiring large capital investments such as technology manufacturing, are prime examples of industries where real options analysis is increasingly used and valued.
Groups of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention can be used by firms within a given industry to better analyze capital budgeting decisions, including those involving real options. For example, a group of DBAR contingent claims can be established which provides hedging opportunities over the distribution of future semiconductor prices. Such ~ a group of claims would allow producers of semiconductors to better hedge their capital budgeting decisions and provide information as to the market's expectation of future prices over the entire distribution of possible price outcomes. This information about the market's expectation of future prices could then also be used in the real options context in order to better evaluate capital budgeting decisions. Similarly, computer manufacturers could use such groups of DBAR contingent claims to hedge against adverse semiconductor price changes.
Information providing the basis for constructing an illustrative group of DBAR
contingent claims on semiconductor prices is as follows:
Underlying Event: Semiconductor Monthly Sales Index: Semiconductor Industry Association Monthly Global Sales Release Current Date: 9/15/99 Last Release Date: 9/2/99 Last Release Month: July, 1999 Last Release Value: 11.55 Billion, USD

Next Release Date: Approx. 10/1/99 Next Release Month: August 1999 Trading Start Date: 9/2/99 Trading End Date: 9/30/99 For reasons of brevity, defined states and opening indicative or illustrative returns resulting from amounts invested in the various states for this example are not shown, but can be readily calculated or will emerge from actual trader investments according to the methods of the present invention, as illustrated in previous examples.
: : Groups of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention can also be used to hedge arbitrary sources of risk due to price discovery processes. For example, fnms involved in competitive bidding for goods or services, whether by sealed bid or open bid markets or auctions, can hedge their investments and other capital expended in preparing the bid by investing in states of a group of DBAR contingent claims comprising ranges of mutually exclusive and collectively 1 S exhaustive market or auction bids. In this way, the group of DBAR
contingent claim serves as a kind of "meta-auction," and allows those who will be participating in the market or auction to invest in the distribution of possible market or auction outcomes, rather than simply waiting for the single outcome representing the market or auction result. Market or auction participants could thus hedge themselves against adverse market or auction developments and outcomes, and, importantly, have access to the entire probability distribution of bids (at least at one point in time) before submitting a bid into the real market or auction. Thus, a group of DBAR claims could be used to provide market data over the entire distribution of possible bids. Preferred embodiments of the present invention thus can help avoid the so-called Winner's Curse phenomenon known to economists, whereby market or auction participants fail rationally to take account of the information on the likely bids of their market or auction competitors.
Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to offer a wide variety of products related to commodities such as fuels, chemicals, base metals, precious metals, agricultural products, etc. The following examples provide a further representative sampling:
- ~ll9-Fuels: Demand-based markets or auctions can be based on measures related to various fuel sources. For example, DBAR contingent claims, including, e.g., digital options, can be based on an underlying event defined as the price of natural gas in Btu's delivered to the Henry Hub, Louisiana.
S Chemicals: Demand-based markets or auctions can be based on measures related to a variety of other chemicals. For example, DBAR contingent claims, including, e.g., digital options, can be based on an underlying event defined as the price of polyethylene.
Base Metals: Demand-based markets or auctions can be based on measures related to various precious metals. For example, DBAR contingent claims, including, e.g., digital options, can be based on an underlying event defined as:,the price per gross ton of #1 Heavy Melt Scrap Iron.
Precious Metals: Demand-based markets or auctions can be based on measures related to various precious metals. For example, DBAR contingent clairrls, including, e.g., digital options, can be based on an underlying event defined as the price per troy ounce of 1 S Platinum delivered to an approved storage facility.
Agricultural Products: Demand-based markets or auctions can be based on measures related to various agricultural products. For example, DBAR contingent claims, including, e.g., digital options, can be based on an underlying event defined as the price per bushel of #2 yellow corn delivered at the Chicago Switching District.
Example 3.1.18: DBAR Hed ing Another feature of the systems and methods of the present invention is the relative ease with which traders can hedge risky exposures. In the following example, it is assumed that a group of DBAR contingent claims has two states (state 1 and state 2, or s1 or s2~, and amounts T~, and Tz are invested in state 1 and state 2, respectively. The unit payout ~~
for state 1 is therefore T2/Ti and for state 2 it is T~/TZ. If a trader then invests amount al in state 1, and state 1 then occurs, the trader in this example would receive the following payouts, P, indexed by the appropriate state subscripts:
PI = a~ * ( TZ + 1) T, + a , If state 2 occurs the trader would receive Pz - 0 If, at some point during the trading period, the trader desires to hedge his exposure, the investment in state 2 to do so is calculated as follows:
~ Tz z T
5This is found by equating the state payouts with the proposed hedge trade, as follows:
P~ = at * (Tz + az + 1) = Pz = az * ( Ti + a~ + 1 T, + a, Tz + a z ) Compared to the calculation required to hedge traditional derivatives, these expressions show that, in appropriate groups of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention, calculating and implementing hedges can be relatively straightforward.
The hedge ratio, a2, just computed for a simple two state example can be adapted to a -group of DBAR contingent claims which is defined over more than two states. In a preferred embodiment of a.group of DBAR contingent claims, the existing investments in states to be hedged can be distinguished from the states on which a future hedge investment is to be made.
The latter states can be called the "complement" states, since they comprise all the states that can occur other than those in which investment by a trader has akeady been made, i.e., they are complementary to the invested states. A mufti-state hedge in a preferred embodiment includes two steps: (1) determining the amount of the hedge investment in the complement states, and (2) given the amount so determined, allocating the amount among the complement states. The amount of the hedge investment in the complement states pursuant to the first step is calculated as a aH Tc c- T
H
where a~ is amount of the hedge investment in the complement states, aH is the amount of the existing investment in the states to be hedged, T~ is the existing amount invested in the complement states, and TH is the amount invested the states to be hedged, exclusive of aH . The second step involves allocating the hedge investment .among the complement states, which can be done by allocating a~ among the complement states in proportion to the existing amounts already invested in each of those states.
An example of a four-state group of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention illustrates this two-step hedging process. ~'or purposes of this example, the following assumptions are made: (i) there are four states, numbered 1 through 4, respectively; (ii) $50, $80, $70 and $40 is invested in each state, (iii) a trader has previously placed a mufti-state investment in the amount of $10 ( ax as defined above) for states 1 and 2; and (iv) the allocation of this mufti-state investment in states 1 and 2 is $3.8462 and $6.15385,.respectively. The amounts invested in each state, excluding the trader's invested amounts, are therefore $46.1538, $73.84615; $70, and $40 for states 1 through 4, respectively. It is noted that the amount invested in the states to be hedged, i.e., states 1 and 2, exclusive of the mufti-state investment of $10, is the quantity TH as defined above.
The first step in a preferred embodiment of the two-step-hedging process is to compute the amount. of the hedge investment to be made in the complement states. As derived above, the amount of the new hedge investment is equal to the amount of the existing investment multiplied by the ratio .of the amount invested in the complement states to the amount invested in the states to be hedged, excluding the trader's existing trades, i.e., $10*($70~$40)/($46.1538+$73.84615) _ $9.16667. The second step in this process is to allocate this amount between the two 15- complement states, i.e., states 3 and 4.
Following the procedures discussed above for allocating rnulti-state investments, the complement state allocation is accomplished by allocating the hedge investment amount --$9.16667 in this example -- in proportion to the existing amount previously invested in the complement states, i.e., $9.16667*$70/$110= $5.83333 for state 3 and $9.16667*$40/$110=
$3.3333 for state 4. Thus, in this example, the trader now has the following amounts invested in states 1 through 4:($3.8462, $6.15385, $5.8333, $3.3333); the total amount invested in each of the four states is $50, $80, $75.83333, and $43.3333); and the returns for each of the four states, based on the total amount invested in each of the four states, would be, respectively, (3.98333, 2.1146; 2.2857, and 4.75). In this example, if state 1 occurs the trader will receive a payout, including the amount invested in state l, of 3.98333*$3.8462+$3_8462=$19.1667 which is equal to the sum invested, so the trader is fully hedged against the occurrence of state 1. Calculations for the other states yield the same results, so that the trader. in this example would be fully hedged irrespective of which state occurs.
As returns can be expected to change throughout the trading period, the trader would correspondingly need to rebalance both the amount of his hedge investment for the complement states as well as the mufti-state allocation among the complement states. In a preferred embodiment, a DBAR contingent claim exchange can be responsible for reallocating mufti-state trades via a suspense account, for example, so the trader can assign the duty of reallocating the mufti-state investment to the exchange. Similarly, the trader can also assign to an exchange the responsibility of determining the amount of the hedge investment in the complement states especially as returns change as a result of trading. The calculation and allocation of this amount can be done by the exchange in a similar fashion to the way the exchange reallocates mufti-state trades to constituent states as investment amounts change.
Example 3.1.19: Quasi-Continuous Trading Preferred embodiments of the systems and methods of the present invention include a : trading period during which returns adjust among defined states for a group of DBAR contingent claims, and a later observation period during which the outcome is ascertained for the event on which the group of claims is based. In preferred embodiments, retains are allocated to the occurrence of a state based on the final distribution of amounts invested over all the states at the end of the trading period. Thus, in each embodiments a trader will not know his returns to a 1 S given state with certainty until the end of a given trading period. The changes in returns or "price discovery" which occur during the trading, period prior to "locking-in" the final returns may provide useful information as to trader expectations regarding finalized outcomes, even though they are only indications as to what the final returns are going to be. Thus, in some preferred embodiments, a trader may not be able to realize profits or losses during the trading period. The hedging illustration of Example 3.1.18, for instance, provides an example of risk reduction but not of locking-in or realizing profit and loss.
In other preferred embodiments; a quasi-continuous market for trading in a group of DBAR contingent claims may be created. In preferred embodiments, a plurality of recurring trading periods may provide traders with nearly continuous opportunities to realize profit and loss. In one such embodiment, the end of one trading period is immediately followed by the opening of a new trading period, and the final invested amount and state returns for a prior trading period are "locked in" as that period ends, and are allocated accordingly when the outcome of the relevant event is later known. As a new trading period begins on the group of DBAR contingent claims related to the same underlying event, a new distribution of invested amounts for states can emerge along with a corresponding new distribution of state returns. In such embodiments, as the successive trading periods are made to open and close more frequently, a quasi-continuous market can be obtained, enabling traders to hedge and realize profit and loss as frequently as they currently do in the traditional markets.
An example illustrates how this feature of the present invention may be implemented.
The example illustrates the hedging of a European digital call option on the yen/dollar exchange S rate (a traditional market option) over a two day period during which the underlying exchange rate changes by one yen per dollar. In this example, two trading periods are assumed for the group of DBAR contingent claims Traditional Option: European Digital Option Payout of Option: Pays 100 million.USD if exchange rate equals or exceeds strike .
price at maturity or expiration Underlying Index: Yen/dollar exchange rate Option Start: 8/12/99 Option Expiration: 8/15/00 Assumed Volatility: 20% annualized Strike Price: 120 Notional: 100 million USD
In this example, two dates are analyzed; 8/12/99 and 8/13/99:
Table 3.1.19-1: Change in Traditional Digital Call Option Value Over Two Days Observation Date 8/12/99 8/13/99 Spot Settlement Date 8/16/99 8/17/99 S of Price for Settlement115.55 116.55 Date Forward Settlement Date 8/15100 8/15/00 Forward Price 109.217107 110.1779 tion Premium 28.333% of Notional 29.8137% of Notional Table 3.1.19-1 shows how the digital call option struck at 120 could, as an example, change in value with an underlying change in the yen/dollar exchange rate. The second column shows that the option is worth 28.333% or $28.333 million on a $100 million notional on 8/12/99 when the underlying exchange rate is 115.55. The third column shows that the value of the option, which pays $100 million should dollar yen equal or exceed 120 at the expiration date, increases to 29.8137% or $29.8137 million per $100 million when the underlying exchange rate has increased by 1 yen to 116.55. Thus, the traditional digital call option generates a profit of $29.81377-$28.333 = $1.48077 million.

This example shows how this profit also could be realized in trading in a group of DBAR
contingent claims with two successive trading periods. It is also assumed for purposes of this example that there are sufficient amounts invested, or liquidity, in both states such that the particular trader's investment does not materially affect the returns to each state. This is a convenient but.not necessary assumption that allows the trader to take the returns to each state "as given" without concern as to how his investment will affect the closing returns for a given trading period. Using information from Table 3.1.19-1, the following closing returns for each state can be derived:
Tradin~~ Period 1:
Current trading period end date: 8/12/99 Underlying Event: Closing level of yen/dollar exchange rate for 8/15/00 settlement, 4 pm EDT
Spot Price for 8/16/99 Settlement: 115.55 State JPY/L1SD <120 for JPY/CTSD ~ 120 for Closing Returns 0.39533 2.5295 For purposes of this example, it is assumed that an illustrative trader has $28.333 million invested in the state that the yen/dollar exchange rate equals or exceeds 120 for 8/15/00 settlement:
. Trading Period 2:
Current trading period end date: 8/13/99 Underlying Event: Closing level of dollar/yen exchange rate for 8/15/00 settlement, 4 pm EDT
Spot Price for 8/17/99 Settlement: 116.55 State JPY/USD <120 for 8/15/00 7PY/LISD Z 120 for 8/15/00 Closin State Returns .424773 2.3542 For purposes of this example, it is also assumed that the illustrative trader has a $70.18755 million hedging investment in the state that the yen/dollar exchange rate is less than 120 for 8/15/00 settlement. It is noted that, for the second period, the closing returns are lower -~25-for the state that the exchange equals or exceeds 120. This is due to the change represented in Table 3.1.19-1 reflecting an assumed change in the underlying market, which would make that state more likely.
The trader now has an investment in each trading period and has locked in a profit of S $1.4807 million, as shown below:
State ~ JPY/USD <120 for 8/15/00 ~ JPY/USD >_ 120 for 8/15/00 Profit and Loss (000.000) $70.18755*.424773- $28.333=$1.48077 $-70.18755+28.333*$2.5295=$1.48077 The illustrative trader in this example has therefore been able to lock-in or realize the profit no matter which state finally occurs. This profit is identical to the profit realized in the traditional digital option, illustrating that systems and methods of the present invention can be used to provide at least daily if not more frequent realization of profits and losses, or that risks can be hedged in virtually real time.
In preferred embodiments, a quasi-continuous time hedge can be accomplished, in general, by the following hedge investment, assuming the effect of the size of the hedge trade 1 S does not materially effect the returns:
1+r H-ar* r 1+r~+~
where rt= closing returns a state in which an investment was originally made at time t at= amount originally invested in the state at time t r°t+i= closing returns at time t+1 to state or states other than the state in which the original investment was made (i.e., the so-called complement states which are all states other than the state or states originally traded which are to be hedged) H= the amount of the hedge investment If H is to be invested in more than one state, then a mufti-state allocation among the constituent states can be performed using the methods and procedures described above. This expression for H allows investors in DBAR contingent claims to calculate the investment amounts for hedging transactions. In the traditional markets, such calculations are often complex and quite difficult.
- fi 26 -Example 3.1.20: Value Units For Investments and Payouts As previously discussed in this specification, the units of investments and payouts used~in embodiments of the present invention can be any unit of economic value recognized by investors, including, for example, currencies, commodities, number of shares, quantities of indices, amounts of swap transactions, or amounts of real estate. The invested amounts and payouts need not be in the same units and can comprise a group or combination of such units, for example 25%
gold, 25% barrels of oil, and 50% Japanese Yen. The previous examples in this specification have generally used U.S. dollars as the value units for investments and payouts.
This Example 3.1.20 illustrates a group of DBAR contingent claims for a common stock in which the invested units and payouts are defined in quantities of shares.
For this example, the terms and conditions of Example 3.1.1 are generally used for the group of contingent claims on MSFT common stock, except for purposes of brevity, only three states are presented in this Example 3.1.20: (0,83], (83, 88], and (88,00]. Also in this Example 3.1.20, invested amounts are in numbers of shares for each state and the exchange makes the conversion for the trader at the 1 S : market price prevailing at the time of the investment. In this example, payouts are made according to a canonical DRF in which a trader receives a quantity of shares equal to the number of shares invested in states that did not occur, in proportion to the ratio of number of shares the trader has invested,in the state that did occur, divided by the total number of shares invested in that state. An indicative distribution of trader demand in units of number of shares is shown below, assuming that the total traded amount is 100,000 shares:
Amount Traded in Return Per Share State Number of if State Occurs Share Unit Returns in Number of Shares 0,83 17,803 4.617 83,88 72,725 .37504 gg~ ~ 9,472 9.5574 If, for instance, MSFT closes at 91 at expiration, then in this example the third state has occurred, and a trader who had previously invested 10 shares in that state would.receive a payout of 10*9.5574 + 10 = 105.574 shares which includes the trader's original investment. Traders who had previously invested in the other two states would lose all of their shares upon application of the canonical DRF of this example.
An important feature of investing in value units other than units of currency is that the magnitude of the observed outcome may well be relevant, as well as the state that occurs based on that outcome. For example, if the investments in this exaanple were made in dollars, the trader -g27-who has a dollar invested in state (88,00] would not care, at least in theory, whether the final price of MSFT at the close of the observation period were 89 or 500. However, if the value units are numbers of shares of stock, then the magnitude of the final outcome does matter, since the trader receives as a payout a number of shares which can be converted to more dollars at a higher outcome price of $91 per share. For instance, for a payout of 105.574 shares, these shares are worth 105.574*$91 = $9,607.23 at the outcome price. Had the outcome price been $125, these shares would have been worth 105.574*125= $13,196.75.
A group of DBAR contingent claims using value units of commodity having a price can therefore possess additional features compared to groups of DBAR contingent claims that offer fixed payouts for a state, regardless of the magnitude of the outcome within that state. These features may prove useful in constructing groups of DBAR contingent claims which are able to readily provide risk and return profiles similar to those provided by traditional derivatives. For example; the group of DBAR contingent claims described in this example could be of great interest to traders who transact in traditional derivatives known as "asset-or-nothing digital options" and "supershares options."
Example 3.1.21: Replication of An Arbitrary Payout Distribution An advantage of the systems and methods of the present invention is that, in preferred embodiments, traders can generate an arbitrary distribution of payouts across the distribution of defined states for a group of DBAR contingent claims. The ability to generate a customized payout distribution may be important to traders, since they may desire to replicate contingent claims payouts that are commonly found in traditional markets, such as those corresponding to long positions in stocks, short positions in bonds, short options positions in foreign exchange, and long option straddle positions, to cite just a few examples. In addition, preferred embodiments of the present invention may enable replicated distributions of payouts which can only be generated with difficulty and expense in traditional markets, such as the distribution of payouts for a long position in a stock that is subject to being "stopped out"
by having a market-maker sell the stock when it reaches a certain price below the market price.
Such stop-loss orders are notoriously difficult to execute in traditional markets, and traders are frequently not guaranteed that the execution will occur exactly at the pre-specified price.
In preferred embodiments, and as discussed above, the generation and replication of arbitrary payout distributions across a given distribution of states for a group of DBAR
- F.28 -contingent claims may be achieved through the use of multi-state investments.
In such embodiments, before making an investment, traders can specify a desired payout for each state or some of the states in a given distribution of states. These payouts form a distribution of desired payouts across the distribution of states for the group of DBAR contingent claims. In preferred embodiments, the distribution of desired payouts may be stored by an exchange, which may also calculate, given an existing distribution of investments across the distribution of states, (1) the total amount required to be invested to achieve the desired payout distribution; (2) the states into which the investment is to allocated; and (3) how much is to be invested in each state so that the desired payout distribution can be achieved. In preferred embodiments, this mufti-state -10 investment is entered into a suspense account maintained by the exchange, which reallocates the I investment among the states as the amounts invested change across the distribution of states. In preferred embodiments, as discussed above, a final allocation is made at the end of the trading period.when returns are finalized.
The discussion in this specification of mufti-state investments has included examples in which it has been assumed that an illustrative trader desires a payout which is the same no matter which state occurs among the constituent states of a mufti-state investment.
To achieve this result, in preferred embodiments the amount invested by the trader in the mufti-state investment can be allocated to the constituent state in proportion to the amounts that have otherwise been invested in the respective constituent states. In preferred embodiments, these investments are reallocated using. the same procedure throughout the trading period as the relative proportion of ariiounts invested in the constituent states changes.
In .other preferred embodiments, a trader may make a mufti-state investment in which the mufti-state allocation is not intended to generate the same payout irrespective of which state among the constituent state occurs. Rather, in such embodiments, the mufti-state investment may be intended to generate a payout distribution which matches some other desired payout distribution of the trader across the distribution of states, such as, for example, for certain digital strips, as discussed in Section 6. Thus, the systems and methods of the present invention do not require amounts invested in mufti-state investments to be allocated in proportion of the amounts otherwise invested in the constituent states of the mufti-statement investment.
Notation previously developed in this specification is used to describe a preferred embodiment of a method by which replication of an arbitrary distribution of payouts can be achieved for a group of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention. The following additional notation, is also used:
A;,~ denotes the i-th row of the matrix A containing the invested amounts by trader i for each of the n states of the group of DBAR contingent claims In preferred embodiments, the allocation of amounts invested in all the states which achieves the desired payouts across the distribution of states can be calculated using, for example, the computer code listing in Table 1 (or functional equivalents known to one of skill in the art), or, in the case where a trader's multi-state investment is small relative to the total investments already made in the group of DBAR contingent claims, the following approximation:
A;-n-~*p;.
where the -1 superscript on the matrix Tj denotes a matrix inverse operation:
Thus, in these embodiments, amounts to be invested to produce an arbitrary distribution payouts can approximately be found by multiplying (a) the inverse of a diagonal matrix with the unit payouts for each state on the diagonal (where the unit payouts are determined from the amounts invested at any given time in the trading period) and (b) a vector containing the trader's desired payouts.
The equation above shows that the amounts to be invested in order to produce a desired payout distribution are a function of the desired payout distribution itself (P;,~) and the amounts otherwise invested across the distribution of states (which are used to form the matrix II, which contains the payouts per unit along its diagonals and zeroes along the off diagonals). Therefore, in preferred embodiments, the allocation of the amounts to be invested in each state will change if either the desired payouts change or if the amounts otherwise invested across the distribution change. As the, amounts otherwise invested in various states can be expected to change during the course of a trading period, in preferred embodiments a suspense account is used to reallocate the invested amounts, A;,~, in response to these changes, as described previously. In preferred embodiments, at the end of the trading period a final allocation is made using the amounts otherwise invested across the distribution of states. The final allocation can typically be performed using the iterative quadratic solution techniques embodied in the computer code listing in Table 1.
Example 3.1.21 illustrates a methodology for generating an arbitrary payout distribution, using the event, termination criteria, the defined states, trading period and other relevant information, as appropriate, from Example 3.1.1, and assuming that the desired mufti-state investment is small in relation to the total amount of investments already made. In Example 3.1.1 above, illustrative investments are shown across the distribution of states representing possible closing prices for MSFT stock on the expiration date of 8/19/99. In that example, the distribution of investment is illustrated for 8/18/99, one day prior to expiration, and the price of . MSFT on this date is given as 85. For purposes of this Example 3.1.21, it is assumed that a trader would like to invest in a group of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention in a way that approximately replicates the profits and losses that would result. from owning one share of MSFT (i.e., a relatively small amount) between the prices of 80 and 90. Iii other words, it is assumed that the trader would like to replicate a traditional long position in ~MSFT with the restrictions that a sell order is to be executed when MSFT
reaches 80 or 90.
Thus, for example, if MSFT closes at 87 on 8/19/99 the trader would expect to have $2 of profit from appropriate investments in a group of DBAR contingent claims. Using the defined states identified in Example 3.1.1, this profit would be approximate since the states are defined to include a range of discrete possible closing prices.
In preferred embodiments, an investment in a state receives the same return regardless of the actual outcome within the state. It is therefore assumed for purposes of this Example 3.1.21 that a trader would accept an appropriate replication of the traditional profit arid loss from a traditional position, subject to only "discretization" error. For purposes of this Example 3.1.21, and in preferred embodiments, it is assumed that the profit and loss corresponding to an actual ~ outcome within a state is determined with reference to the price which falls exactly in between ' the upper and lower bounds of the state as measured in units of probability, i.e., the "state average." For this Example 3.1.21, the following desired payouts can be calculated for each of the states the amounts to be invested in each state and the resulting investment amounts to achieve those payouts:
-~31-Table 3.1.21-1 States State Average Desired PayoutInvestment ($) ($) Which Generates Desired Payout ($) (0,80] NA 80 0.837258 (80,80.5] 80.33673 80.33673 0.699493 (80.5,81] 80.83349 80.83349 1.14091 (81,81.5] 81.33029 81.33029 1 .755077 (81.5,82] 81.82712 81.82712 _ 2.549131 (82,82.5] 82.32401 82.32401 3.498683 (82.5,83] 82.82094 82.82094 4.543112 (83,83.5]' 83.31792 83.31792 5.588056 (83.5,84] 83.81496 83.81496 6.512429 (84,84.5] 84.31204 84.31204 7.206157 (84.5,85] 84.80918 84.80918 7.572248 (85,85.5] 85.30638 85.30638 7.555924 ..

(85.5,86] 85:80363 85.80363 7.18022 (86,86.5] 86.30094 86.30094 6.493675 (86.5,87] 86.7983 86.7983 5.59628 (87,87.5] 87.29572 87.29572 4.599353 (87-5'88] 87.7932 87.7932 3.611403 (88,88.5] 88.29074 88.29074 2.706645 (88.5,89] 88.78834 88.78834 1.939457 (89,89.5] 89'.28599 89.28599 1.330046 . (89.5,90] 89.7837 89.7837 0.873212 (90,o] NA 90 1.2795 The far right column of Table 3.1.21-1 is the result of the matrix computation described above.
The payouts used to construct the matrix II for this Example 3.1.21 are one plus the returns S shown in Example 3.1.1 for each state.
Pertinently the systems and methods of the present invention may be used to achieve almost any arbitrary payout or return profile, e.g., a long position, a short position, an option "straddle", etc., while maintaining limited liability and the other benefits of the invention described in this specification.
As discussed above, if many traders make mufti-state investments, in a preferred embodiment an iterative procedure is used to allocate all of the mufti-state investments to their respective constituent states. Computer code, as previously described and apparent to one of skill in the art, can be implemented to allocate each mufti-state investment among the constituent states depending upon the distribution of amounts otherwise invested and the trader's desired payout distribution.

Example 3.1.22: Emerging Market Currencies Corporate and investment portfolio managers recognize the utility of options to hedge exposures to foreign exchange movements. In the G7 currencies, liquid spot and forward S markets support an extremely efficient options market. In contrast, many emerging market currencies lack the liquidity to support efficient, liquid spot and forward markets because of their small economic base. Without ready access to a.source of tradable underlying supply, pricing and risk control of options in emerging market currencies are difficult or impossible.
Governmental intervention and credit constraints further inhibit transaction flows in 10. emerging market currencies. Certain governments choose to restrict the convertibility of their currency for a variety of reasons, thus reducing access to liquidity at any price and effectively preventing option market-makers from gaining access to a tradable underlying supply.
Mismatches between sources of local liquidity and creditworthy counterparties further restrict access to a tradable underlying supply. Regional banks that service local customers have access 15 to indigenous liquidity but poor credit ratings while multinational commercial and investment banks with superior credit ratings have limited access to liquidity. Because credit considerations prevent external market participants from taking on significant exposures to local counterparties, transaction choices are limited.
The foreign exchange market has responded to this lack of liquidity by making use of 20 non-deliverable forwards (NDFs) which, by definition, do not require an exchange of underlying currency. Although NDFs have met with some success, their utility is still constrained by a lack of liquidity. Moreover, the limited liquidity available to NDFs is generally insufficient to support an active options market.
Groups of DBAR contingent claims can be structured using the system and methods of 25 the present invention to support an active options market in emerging market currencies.
In addition to the general advantages of the demand-based trading system, products on emerging market currencies will provide the following new opportunities for trading and risk management:
(1) Credit enhancement. An investment bank can use demand-based trading emerging market 30 currency products to overcome existing credit barriers. The ability of a demand-based market or auction to process only buy orders, combined with the limited liability of option payout profiles (vs. forward contracts), allows banks to precisely define the limits of their counterparty credit exposure and, hence, to trade with local market institutions, increasing participation and liquidity.
Example 3.1.23: Central Bank Target Rates Portfolio managers and market-makers formulate market views based in part on their forecasts for future movements in central bank target rates. When the Federal Reserve (Fed);
European Central Bank (ECB) or Bank of Japan (BOJ), for example, changes their target rate or when market participants adjust their expectations about future rate moves, global equity and fixed income financial markets can react quickly and dramatically.
~ Market participants currently take views on central bank target rates by trading 3-month interest rate futures, such as Eurodollar futures for the Fed and Euribor futures for the ECB.
Although these markets are quite liquid, significant risks impair trading in such contracts:
futures contracts have a 3-month maturity while central bank target rates.
change overnight; and models for credit spreads and term structure are required for futures pricing.
Market participants additionally express views on the target Fed funds rate by trading Fed funds futures, which are based on the overnight Fed funds rate. Although less risky than Eurodollar futures, significant risks also impair trading in Fed funds futures: the overnight Fed fluids rate can differ, sometimes significantly, from the target Fed funds rate due to overnight liquidity spikes and month-end effects; and, Fed fiends futures frequently cannot accommodate the full volumes that investment managers would like to execute at a given market price.
Groups of DBAR contingent claims can be structured using the system and methods of the present invention to develop an explicit mechanism by which market participants can express views regarding central bank target rates. For example, demand-based markets or auctions can be based on central bank policy parameters such as the Federal Reserve Target Fed Funds Rate, the Bank of Japan Official Discount Rate, or the Bank of England Base Rate.
For example, the underlying event may be defined as the Federal Reserve Target Fed Funds Rate as of June 1, 2002. Because demand-based trading products settle using the target rate of interest, maturity and credit mismatches no longer pose market barriers.
In addition to the general advantages of the demand-based trading system, products on central bank target rates may provide the following new advantages for trading and risk management:

(1) No basis risk. Since demand-based trading products settle using the target rate of interest, there is no maturity mismatch and no credit mismatch. Demand-based trading products for central bank target rates have no basis risk.
(2) An exact date match to central bank meetings. Demand-based trading products can be structured to allow investors to take views on specific meetings by matching the date of expiry of a contract with the date of the central bank meeting.
(3) A direct wa ty o express views on infra-meetin moves. Demand-based trading products allow special tailoring so that portfolio managers can take a view on whether or not a central bank will change its target rate infra-meeting..
(4) ~Mana~ing the event risk associated with a central bank meeting. Almost all market .participants have portfolios that are significantly affected by shifts in target rates. Market participants can use demand-based trading options on central bank target rates to lower their portfolio's overall volatility.
(S) Mana '~n~ short-term fundin costs. Banks and large corporations often borrow short-term 1 S .. funds at a rate highly correlated with central bank target rates, e.g., U.S. banks borrow at a rate that closely follows target Fed funds. These institutions may better manage their funding costs using demand-based trading products on central bank rates.
Example 3.1.24: Weather In recent years, market participants have expressed increasing interest in a market for derivative instruments related to weather as a means to insure against adverse.weather outcomes.
Despite greater recognition of the role of weather in economic activity, the market for weather derivatives has been relatively slow to develop. Market-makers in traditional over-the-counter markets often lack the means to redistribute their risk because of limited liquidity and lack of an underlying instrument. The market for weather derivatives is further hampered by poor price discovery.
A group of DBAR contingent claims can be constructed using the methods and systems of the present invention to provide market participants with a market price for the probability that a particular weather metric will be above or below a given level. For example, participants in a demand-based market or auction on cooling degree days (CDDs) or on heating degree days (HDDs) in New York from November 1, 2001 through March 31, 2002 may be able to see at a glance the market consensus price that cumulative CDDs or HDDs will exceed certain levels.

The event observation could be specified as taking place at a preset location such as the Weather Bureau Army Navy Observation Station #14732. Alternatively, participants in a demand-based market or auction on wind-speed in Chicago may be able to see at a glance the market consensus price that cumulative wind-speeds will exceed, certain levels.
S Example 3.1.25: Financial Instruments . Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to offer a wide variety of products on commonly offered financial instruments or structured financial products related to fixed income securities, equities, foreign exchange, interest rates, and indices, and any derivatives thereof. When the underlying economic event is a change (or degree of change) in a financial instrument or product, the possible outcomes can include changes which are positive, negative or equal to zero when there is no change, and amounts of each positive and negative change. The following examples provide a further representative sampling:
Equity Prices: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
contingent.claims, including, for example, digital options, based on prices for equity securities listed on recognized exchanges throughout the world. For example, DBAR
contingent claims can be based on.an underlying event defined as the closing price each week of Juniper Networks. The underlying event can also be defined using an alternative measure, such as the volume weighted average price during any day.
Fixed Income Securi , Prices: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on a variety of fixed income securities such as government T-bills, T-notes, and T-bonds, commercial paper, CD's, zero coupon bonds, corporate, and municipal bonds, and mortgage-backed securities. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an.underlying event defined as the closing price each week of Qwest Capital Funding 7%4 % notes, due February of 2011. The underlying event can also be defined using an alternative measure, such as the volume weighted average price during any day. DBAR contingent claims on government and municipal obligations can be traded in a similar way.
Hybrid Securit Pte: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on hybrid securities that contain both fixed-income and equity features, such as convertible bond prices. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the closing price each week of Amazon.com 43/< % convertible bonds due - fi3~ -February 2009. , The underlying event can also be defined using an alternative measure, such as the volume weighted average price during any day.
Interest Rates: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to bade DBAR
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on interest rate measures such as LIBOR and other money market rates, an index of AAA corporate bond yields, or any of the fixed income securities listed above. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the fixing price each week of 3-month LIBOR rates. Alternatively, the underlying event could be defined as an average of an interest.rate over a fixed length of time, such as a week or month.
: Foreign Exchange: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, based on foreign exchange rates. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based an underlying event defined as the exchange rate of the Korean Won on any day.
Price & Retum Indices: Demand-based markets or auctions can be structured to trade DBAR contingent claims, including, for example; digital options, based on a broad variety of financial instrument price indices,_including those for equities (e.g., S&P 500), interest rates; commodities, etc. For example, DBAR contingent claims can be based on an underlying event defined as the closing price each quarter of the S&P
Technology index. The underlying event can also be defined using an alternative measure, such as the wolume.weighted average price during any day. Alternatively, other index measurements can be used such as return instead of price.
Swaps: Demand-based markets or auctions can-be structured to trade DBAR
contingent claims;.including, for example, digital options, based on interest rate swaps and other swap based transactions. In this example, discussed fiuther in an embodiment described in Section 9, digital options traded in a demand-based market or auction are based on an underlying event defined as the 10 year swap rate at which a fixed 10 year yield is received against paying a floating 3 month LIBOR rate. The rate may be determined using a common fixing convention.
Other derivatives on any security or other financial product or instrument may be used as the underlying instrument for an event of economic significance in a demand-based market or auction. For example, such derivatives can include futures, forwards, swaps, floating rate notes and other structured financial products. Alternatively, derivatives strategies, securities (as well as other financial products or instruments) and derivatives thereof can be converted into equivalent DBAR contingent claims or into replication sets of DBAR contingent claims, such as digitals (for example, as in the embodiments discussed in Sections 9 and 10) and traded as a demand-enabled product alongside DBAR contingent claims in the same demand-based market or auction.
3.2 DBAR Portfolios It may be desirable to combine a number of groups of DBAR contingent claims based on different events into a single portfolio. In this way, traders can invest amounts within the distribution of defined states corresponding to a single event as well as across the distributions of : states corresponding to all the groups of contingent claims in the portfolio. In preferred embodiments, the payouts to the amounts invested in this fashion can therefore be a function of a relative comparison of all the outcome states in the respective groups of DBAR
contingent claims to each other. Such a comparison may be based upon the amount invested in each outcome state in the distribution for each group of contingent claims as well as other qualities, parameters or characteristics of the outcome state (e.g., the magnitude of change for each security underlying the respective groups of contingent claims). In this way, more complex and varied payout and return profiles can be achieved using the systems and methods of the present invention. Since a preferred embodiment of a demand reallocation function (DRF) can operate on a portfolio of DBAR contingent claims, such a portfolio is referred to as a DBAR.Portfolio, or DBARP. A
DBARP is a preferred embodiment of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention based on a mufti-state, mufti-event DRF.
In a preferred embodiment of a DBARP involving different events relating to different financial products, a DRF is employed in which returns for each contingent claim in the portfolio are determined by (i) the actual magnitude of change for each underlying financial product and (ii) how much has been invested in each state in the distribution. A large amount invested in a financial product, such as a common stock, on the long side will depress the returns to defined states on the long side of a corresponding group of DBAR contingent claims.
Given the inverse relationship in preferred embodiments between amounts invested in and returns from a particular state, one advantage to a DBAR portfolio is that it is not prone to speculative bubbles. More specifically, in preferred embodiments a massive influx of long side trading, for example, will increase the returns to short side states, thereby increasing.returns and attracting investment in those states.
- ~3~ -The following notation is used to explain further preferred embodiments of DBARP:
p; is the actual magnitude of change for financial product i W; is the amount of successfi~l investments in financial product i L; is the amount of unsuccessful investments in financial product i f is the system transaction fee L is the aggregate losses = ~ L ;
r y; is the normalized returns for successful trades =
. . ~ ~~ y is the payout per value unit invested in financial product i for a successful investment 10' rP; is the return per unit invested in financial product i for a successful investment The payout principle of a preferred embodiment of a DBARP is to return to a successful investment a portion of aggregate losses scaled by the normalized return for the successful investment, and to return nothing to unsuccessful investments. Thus, in a preferred embodiment a large actual return on a relatively lightly traded financial product will benefit from being allocated a high proportion of the unsuccessful investments.
Y. * L
Wr rp; = Y' * L -1 W, As explained below, the correlations of returns across securities is important in preferred embodiments to determine payouts and returns in a DBARP.
An example illustrates the operation of a DBARP according to the present invention. For purposes of this example, it is assumed that a portfolio contains two stocks, IBM and MSFT
(Microsoft) and that the following information applies (e.g., predetermined termination criteria):
Trading start date: 9/1/99 Expiration date: 10/1/99 Current trading period start date: 9/1/99 - r39-Current trading period end date: 9/5/99 Current date: 9/2/99 IBM start price: 129 MSFT start price: 96 S Both IBM and MSFT Ex-dividends No transaction fee In this example, states can be defined so that traders can invest for IBM and MSFT to either depreciate or appreciate over the period. It is also assumed that the distribution of amounts invested in the various states is the following.at the close of trading for the current trading period:
Financial Product D reciate State A reciate State MSFT $100 million $120 million $80 million $65 million The amounts invested express greater probability assessments that MSFT will likely appreciate over the period and IBM will likely depreciate.
For purposes of this example, it is further assumed that on the expiration date of 10/1/99, the following actual outcomes for prices are observed:
MSFT: 106 (appreciated by 10.42%) IBM 127 (depreciated by 1.55%) In this example, there is $100 + $65 = $165 million to distribute from the unsuccessful investments to the successful investments, and, for the successful investments, the relative performance of MSFT (10/42/(10.42+1.55)=.871) is higher than for IBM
(1.55/10.42+1.55)=.229). In a preferred embodiment, 87.1% of the available returns is allocated to the successful MSFT traders, with the remainder due the successful IBM
traders, and with the following returns computed for each state:
MSFT: $120 million of successful investment produces a payout of .871 *$165 million =
$143.72 million for a return to the successful traders of ... . .
120M + 143.72M -1=119.77%

IBM: $80 million in successful investment produces a payout of (1-.871)*$165 million _ $21.285 million, for a return to the successful traders of 80M + 21.285M
-1= 26.6%

- ~ 4~ -The returns in this example and in preferred embodiments are a function not only of the amounts invested in each group of DBAR contingent claims, but also the relative magnitude of the changes in prices for the underlying financial products or in the values of the underlying events of economic performance. In this specific example, the MSFT traders receive higher returns since MSFT significantly outperformed IBM. In other words, the MSFT longs were "more correct" than the IBM shorts.
The operation of a DBARP is further illustrated by assuming instead that the prices of both MSFT and IBM changed by the same magnitude, e.g., MSFT went up 10%, and IBM went down 10%, but otherwise maintaining the assumptions for this example. In this scenario, $165 million of returns would remain to distribute from the unsuccessful investments but these are allocated equally to MSFT and IBM successful investments, or $82.5 million to each. Under this scenario the returns are:
120M + 82.5M
MSFT: -1= 68.75%

80M + 82.5M
IBM: -1=103.125%

The IBM returns in this scenario are 1.5 times the returns to the MFST
investments, since less was invested in the IBM group of DBAR contingent claims than in the MSFT
group.
This result confirms that preferred embodiments of the systems and methods of the present invention provide incentives for traders to make large investments, i.e. promote liquidity, where it is needed in order to have an aggregate amount invested sufficient to provide a fair indication of trader expectations.
The payouts in this example depend upon both the magnitude of change in the underlying stocks as well as the correlations between such changes. A statistical estimate of these expected changes and correlations can be made in order to compute expected returns and payouts during trading and at the close of each trading period. While making such an investment may be somewhat more complicated that in a DBAR range derivative, as discussed above, it is still readily apparent to one of skill in the art from this specification or from practice of the invention.
The preceding example of a DBARP has been illustrated with events corresponding to closing prices of underlying securities. DBARPs of the present invention are not so limited and may be applied to any events of economic significance, e.g., interest rates, economic statistics, commercial real estate rentals, etc. In addition, other types of DRFs for use with DBARPs are apparent to one of ordinary skill in the art, based on this specification or practice of the present invention.
4. RISK CALCULATIONS
Another advantage of the groups of DBAR contingent claims according to the present invention is the ability to provide transparent risk calculations to traders, market risk managers, and other interested parties.. Such risks can include market risk and credit risk, which are discussed below 4.1 Market Risk :~ . Market riskcalculations are typically performed so that traders have information regarding the probability distribution of profits and losses applicable to their portfolio of active trades. For all trades associated with a group of DBAR contingent claims, a trader might want to know, for example, the dollar loss associated with the bottom fifth percentile of profit and loss.
The bottom fifth percentile corresponds to a loss amount which the trader knows, with a 95%
statistical confidence, would not be exceeded. For the purposes of this specification, the loss amount associated with a given statistical confidence (e.g., 95%, 99%) for an individual investment is denoted the capital-at-risk ("CAR"). In preferred embodiments of the present invention, a CAR can be computed not only for an individual investment but also for a plurality of investments related to for the same event or for multiple events.
In the financial industry, there are three common methods that are currently employed to compute CAR: (1) Value-at-Risk ("VAR"); (2) Monte Carlo Simulation ("MCS");
and (3) Historical Simulation ("HS") 4.1.1 Capital-At-Risk Deterrriinations Usin~Value-At-Risk Techniques VAR is a method that commonly relies upon calculations of the standard deviations and correlations of price changes for a group of trades. These standard deviations and correlations are typically computed from historical data. The standard deviation data are typically used to compute the CAR for each trade individually.
To illustrate the use of VAR with a group of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention, the following assumptions are made: (i) a trader has made a traditional purchase of a stock, say $100 of IBM; (ii) using previously computed standard deviation data, it is determined that the annual standard deviation for IBM is 30%; (iii) as is commonly the case, the price changes for IBM have a normal distribution; and (iv) the percentile of loss to be used is the - ll 42 -bottom fifth percentile. From standard normal tables, the bottom fifth percentile of loss corresponds to approximately 1.645 standard deviations, so the CAR in this example -- that is, loss for the IBM position that would not be exceeded with 95% statistical confidence -- is 30%*1.645*$100, or $49.35. A similar calculation, using similar assumptions, has been made for a $200 position in GM, and the CAR computed for GM is $65.50. If, in this example, the computed correlation, S, between the prices of IBM and GM stock is .5, the CAR
for the portfolio containing both the IBM and GM positions may be expressed as:
CAR=~~1.645a~M a yM )2 + (1.645acM a~cM ~ + 2S1.645a,~M a yM * I .645acM QcM
I0 =,/49.352 + 65.502 + 2 *.5 * 49.35 * 65.5 = 99.79 where_a is the investment in dollars, a is the standard deviation, and S is the correlation.
These computations are commonly represented in matrix form as:
. C is the correlation matrix of the underlying events, w is the vector containing the CAR for each active position in the portfolio, and 1 S wT is the transpose of W.
In preferred embodiments, C is a y x y matrix, where y is the number of active positions in the portfolio, and where the elements of C are:
c;~=1 when i~ i.e., has 1's on the diagonal, and otherwise c;,~= the correlation between the ith and jth events (49.35 65.5) (.5 '1 ) ( 49.35) 20 ~' CAR= w T * C * w 65.5 In preferred embodiments, several steps implement the VAR methodology for a group of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention. The steps are first listed, and details of each step are then provided. The steps are as follows:
(1) beginning with a distribution of defined states for a group of DBAR
contingent 25 claims, computing the standard deviation of returns in value units (e.g., dollars) for each investment in a given state;
(2) performing a matrix calculation using the standard deviation of returns for each state and the correlation matrix of returns for the states within the same distribution of states, to obtain the standard deviation of returns for all investments in a group of DBAR
contingent claims;
_r43_ (3) adjusting the number resulting from the computation in step (2) for each investment so that it corresponds to the desired percentile of loss;
(4) arranging the numbers resulting from step (3) for each distinct DBAR
contingent claim: in the portfolio into a vector, w, having dimension equal to the number of distinct DBAR
S contingent claims;
(5) creating a correlation matrix including the correlation of each pair of the underlying events for each respective DBAR contingent claim in the portfolio; and (6) calculating the square root of the product of w, the correlation matrix created in step (S), and the transpose of w.
The result is CAR using the desired percentile of loss, for all the groups of DBAR
contingent claims in the portfolio.
In preferred embodiments, the VAR methodology of steps (1)-(6) above can be applied to an arbitrary group of DBAR contingent claims as follows. For purposes of illustrating this methodology, it is assumed that all investments are made in DBAR range derivatives using a canonical DRF as previously described. . Similar-analyses apply to other forms of DRFs.
In step (1), the standard deviation of returns per unit of amount invested for each state i for each group of DBAR contingent claim is computed as follows:
T _1= (1-q~) - r T q~
where a; is the standard deviation of returns per unit of amount invested in each state i, T; is the total ariiount invested in state i; T is the sum of all amounts invested across the distribution of states; q; is the implied probability of the occurrence of state i derived from T and T;; and r; is the return per unit of investment in state i. In this preferred embodiment, this standard deviation is a function of the amount invested in each state and total amount invested across the distribution of states, and is also equal to the square root of the unit return for the state.
If ac; is the amount invested in state i, a;*a; is the standard deviation in units of the amount invested (e.g., dollars) for each state i.
Step (2) computes the standard deviation for all investments in a group of DBAR
contingent claims. This step (2) begins by calculating the correlation between each pair of states _ 1~ _ for every possible pair within the same distribution of states for a group of DBAR contingent claims. For a canonical DRF, these correlations may be computed as follows:
T,. *T; __ ~i *~; _1 _1 P.,;
(T_T)*(T_T;) (1-qt)*(1-q;) r, *r; 6; *~;
where p;,~ is the correlation between state i and state j. In preferred embodiments, the returns to each state are negatively correlated since the occurrence of one state (a successful investment) precludes the occurrence of other states (unsuccessful investments). If there are only two states in the distribution of states, then T~ T-T; and the correlation p;~ is -1;
i.e., an investment in state i is successful and in state j is not, or vice versa, if i and j are the only two states. In preferred embodiments where there are more than two states, the correlation falls in the range between 0 and -1 (the correlation is exactly 0 if and only if one of the states has implied probability equal to one). In step (2) of the VAR methodology, the correlation coefficients p;~ are put into a matrix CS (the subscript s indicating correlation among states for the same event) which contains a number of rows and columns equal to the number of defined states for the group of DBAR
contingent claims. The correlation matrix contains 1's along the diagonal, is symmetric, and the element at the i-th row and j-th column of the matrix is equal to p;~. From step (1) above, a n x1 vector U is constructed having a dimension equal to the number of states n, in the group of DBAR contingent claims, with each element of U being equal to a;*a;. The standard deviation, wk , of returns for all investments in states within the distribution of states defining the kth group of DBAR contingent claims can be calculated as follows:
wk = UT * Cs * U
Step (3) involves adjusting the previously computed standard deviation, wk, for every group of DBAR contingent claims in a portfolio by an amount corresponding to a desired or acceptable percentile of loss. For purposes of illustration, it is assumed that investment returns have a normal distribution function; that a 95% statistical confidence for losses is desirable; and that the standard deviations of returns for each group of DBAR contingent claims, wk , can be multiplied by 1.645, i.e., the number of standard deviations in the standard normal distribution corresponding to the bottom fifth percentile. A normal distribution is used for illustrative purposes, and other types of distributions (e.g., the Student T
distribution).can be used to compute the number of standard deviations corresponding to the any percentile of interest. As - i45 -discussed above, the maximurri amount that can be lost in preferred embodiments of canonical DRF implementation of a group of DBAR contingent claims is the.amount invested.
Accordingly, for this illustration the standard deviations wk are adjusted to reflect the constraint that the most that can be lost is the smaller of (a) the total amount invested and (b) the percentile loss of interest associated with the CAR calculation for the group of DBAR contingent claims, i.e.:
w,~ = min(1.645 * w,~ , ~ a; ) i=l..n In effect, this updates the standard deviation for each event by substituting for it a CAR
value that reflects a multiple of the standard deviation corresponding to an extreme loss percentile (e.g:, bottom fifth) or the total invested amount, whichever is smaller.
Step (4) involves taking the adjusted wk, as developed in step (4) for each of m groups of DBAR contingent claims, and arranging them into an y x 1 dimensional column vector, w, each eleriient of which contains wk , k=l ..y.
Step (5) involves the development of a symmetric correlation matrix, Ce, which has a number of rows and columns equal to the number of groups of DBAR contingent claims, y. in which the trader has one or more investments. Correlation matrix Ce can be estimated from historical data or may be available more directly, such as the correlation matrix among foreign exchange rates, interest rates, equity indices, commodities, and other financial products available from JP Morgan's R.iskMetrics database. Other sources of the correlation information for matrix Ce are known to those of skill in the art. Along the diagonals of the correlation matrix Ce are 1's, and the entry at the i-th row and j-th column of the matrix contains the correlation between the i-th and j-th events which define the i-th and j-th DBAR contingent claim for all such possible pairs among the m active groups of DBAR contingent claims in the portfolio.
In Step (6), the CAR for the entire portfolio of m groups of DBAR contingent claims is found by performing the following matrix computation, using each wk from step (4) arrayed into vector w and its transpose wT:
CAR = wT * Ce * w This CAR value for the portfolio of groups of DBAR contingent claims is an amount of loss that will not be exceeded with the associated statistical confidence used in Steps (1)-(6) above (e.g., in this illustration, 95%).

Example 4.1.1-1: VAR.-based CAR Calculation An example further illustrates the calculation of a VAR-based CAR for a portfolio containing two groups of DBAR range derivative contingent claims (i.e., y=2) with a canonical DRF on two common stocks, IBM and GM. For this example, the following assumptions are made: (i) for each of the two groups of DBAR contingent claims, the relevant underlying event upon which the states are defined is the respective closing price of each stock one month forward; (ii) there are only three states defined for each event: "low", "medium", and "high,"
corresponding to ranges of possible closing prices on that date; (iii) the posted returns for IBM
and GM respectively for the three respective states are, in U.S. dollars, (4, .6667, 4) and (2.333, 1.5, 2.333); (iv) the exchange fee is zero; (v) for the 1BM group of contingent claims, the trader has one dollar invested in the state "low", three dollars invested in the state "medium," and two dollars invested in the state "high"; (vi) for the GM group of contingent claims, the trader has a single investment in the amount of one dollar in the state "medium"; (vii) the desired or acceptable percentile of loss in the fifth percentile, assuming a normal distribution; and (viii) the estimated correlation of the price changes of IBM and GM is .5 across the distribution of states for each stock.
Steps (1)-(6), described above, are used to implement VAR in order to compute CAR for this example. From Step (1), the standard deviations of state returns per unit of amount invested in each state for the IBM and GM groups of contingent claims are, respectively, (2, .8165, 2) and (1.5274, 1.225, 1.5274). In further accordance with Step (1) above, the amount invested in each state in the respective group of contingent claims, a.;; is multiplied by the previously calculated standard deviation of state returns per investment; a;, so that the standard deviation of returns per state in dollars for each claim equals, for the IBM group: (2, 2.4495, 4) and, for the GM group, (0,1.225, 0).
In accordance with Step (2) above, for each of the two groups of DBAR
contingent claims in this example, a correlation matrix between any pair of states, CS, is constructed, as follows:
-.6124 -.25 CSB"' - -.6124 1 -.6124 -.25 -.6124 _ r.47 _ 1 -.5345 -.4286 Cs M - -.5345 1 -.5345 -.4286 -.5345 1 where the left matrix is the correlation between each pair of state returns for the IBM group of contingent claims and the right matrix is the corresponding matrix for the GM
group of S contingent claims:
Also according to step (2) above, for each of the two groups of contingent claims, the standard deviation of returns per state.in dollars, oc;a;, for each investment in this example can be arranged in a vector with dimension equal to three (i.e., the number of states):

U,B,N = 2.4495 Uc~, =1.225 4 p . where the vector on the left contains the standard deviation in dollars of returns per state for the IBM group of contingent claims, and the vector on the right contains the corresponding information for the GM group of contingent claims. Further in accordance with Step (2) above, a matrix calculation can be performed to compute the total standard deviation for all investments in each of the two groups of contingent claims, respectively:
w, =~UBM *CBM *Uranr =2 wz = Ucnr * CJ M * UcM =1.225 where the quantity on the left is the standard deviation for all investments in the distribution of the IBM group of contingent claims, and the quantity on the right is the corresponding standard deviation for the GM group of contingent claims.
In accordance with step (3) above, w1 and w2 are adjusted by multiplying each by 1.645 {corresponding to a CAR loss percentile of the bottom fifth percentile assuming a normal distribution) and then taking the lower of (a) that resulting value and (b) the maximum amount that can be lost, i.e., the amount invested in all states for each group of contingent claims:
w, = min(2 * 1.645,6) = 3.29 wz = min(2 * 1.225,1) =1 where the left quantity is the adjusted standard deviation of returns for all investments across the distribution of the IBM group of contingent claims, and the right quantity is the corresponding amount invested in the GM group of contingent claims. These two quantities, w1 and w2, are the CAR values for the individual groups of DBAR contingent claims respectively, corresponding to a statistical confidence of 95%. In other words, if the normal distribution assumptions that have been made with respect to the state returns are valid, then a trader, for example, could be 95%
confident that losses on the IBM groups of contingent claims would not exceed $3.29.
Proceeding now with Step (4) in the VAR process described above, the quantities w1 and w2 are placed into a vector which has a dimension of two, equal to the number of groups of DBAR contingent claims in the illustrative trader's portfolio:
w=
3.29 According to Step (S), a correlation matrix Ce with two rows and two columns, is either estimated from historical data or obtained from some other source (e.g., RiskMetrics), as known to one of skill in the art. Consistent with the assumption for this illustration that the estimated correlation between the price changes of IBM and GM is 0.5, the correlation matrix for the underlying events is as follows:
_ 1 .5 .
Ce .5 1 Proceeding with Step (6), a matrix multiplication is performed by pre- and post-multiplying Ce by the transpose of w and by w, and taking the square root of the resulting product:
CAR = wT * Ce * w = 3.8877 This means that for the portfolio in this example, comprising the three investments in the IBM
group of contingent claims and the single investment in the GM group of contingent claims, the trader can have a 95% statistical confidence he will not have losses in excess of $3.89.
4.1.2 Capital-At-Risk Determinations Using Monte Carlo Simulation Technigues Monte Carlo Simulation ("MCS") is another methodology that is frequently used in the financial industry to compute CAR. MCS is frequently used to simulate many representative scenarios for a given group of financial products, compute profits and losses for each representative scenario, and then analyze the resulting distribution of scenario profits and losses.
For example, the bottom fifth percentile of the distribution of the scenario profits and losses would correspond to a loss for which a trader could have a 95% confidence that it would not be exceeded. In a preferred embodiment, the MCS methodology can be adapted for the computation of CAR for a portfolio of DBAR contingent claims as follows.
_ rlmj _ Step (1) of the MCS methodology involves estimating the statistical distribution for the events underlying the DBAR contingent claims using conventional econometric techniques; such as GARCH. If the portfolio being analyzed has more than one group of DBAR
contingent claim, then the distribution estimated will be what is commonly known as a multivariate statistical distribution which describes the statistical relationship between and among the events in the portfolio. For example, if the events are underlying closing prices for stocks and stock price changes have a normal distribution, then the estimated stadsdcal distribution would be a multivariate normal distribution containing parameters relevant for the expected price change for each stock, its standard deviation, and correlations between every pair of stocks in the portfolio.
- Multivariate statistical distribution is typically estimated from historical time series data on the underlying events (e.g., history of prices for stocks) using conventional econometric techniques.
Step (2) of the MCS methodology involves using the estimated statistical distribution of Step (1) in order to simulate the representative scenarios.- Such simulations can be performed using simulation methods contained in such reference works as Numerical Recipes in C or by 1 S using simulation software such as @Risk package available from Palisade, or using other methods known to one of skill in the art. For each simulated scenario, the DRF
of each group of DBAR contingent claims in the portfolio determines the payouts and profits and losses on the portfolio computed.
Using the above two stock example involving GM and IBM used above to demonstrate VAR techniques for calculating CAR, a scenario simulated by MCS techniques might be "High"
for IBM and "Low" for GM, in which case the trader with the above positions would have a four dollar profit for the.IBM contingent claim and a one dollar loss for the GM
contingent claim, and a total profit of three dollars. In step (2), many such scenarios are generated so that a resulting distribution of profit and loss is obtained. The resulting profits and losses can be arranged into ascending order so that, for example, percentiles corresponding to any given profit and loss number can be computed. A bottom fifth percentile, for example, would correspond to a loss for which the trader could be 95% confident would not be exceeded, provided that enough scenarios have been generated to provide an adequate representative sample. This number could be used as the CAR value computed using MCS.for a group of DBAR contingent claims.
Additionally, statistics such as average profit or loss, standard deviation, skewness, kurtosis and other similar quantities can be computed from the generated profit and loss distribution, as known by one of skill in the art.

4.1.3 Capital-At-Risk Determination Using Historical Simulation Techniques Historical Simulation ("HS") is another method used to compute CAR values. HS
is comparable to that of MCS in that it relies upon the use of representative scenarios in order to compute a distribution of profit and loss for a portfolio. Rather than rely upon simulated S scenarios from an estimated probability distribution, however, HS uses historical data for the scenarios. In a preferred embodiment, HS can be adapted to apply to a portfolio of DBAR
contingent claims as follows.
Step (1) involves obtaining, for each of the underlying events corresponding to each group of DBAR contingent claims, a historical time series of outcomes for the events. For example, if the events are stock closing prices, time series of closing prices for each stock can be obtained from a historical database such as those available from Bloomberg, Reuters, or Datastream or other data sources known to someone of skill in the art.
Step (2) involves using each observation in the historical data from Step (1) to compute payouts using the DRF for each group of DBAR contingent claims in the portfolio. From the payouts for each group for each historical observation, a portfolio profit and loss can be computed. This results in a distribution of profits and losses corresponding to the historical scenarios, i.e., the profit and loss that would have been obtained had the trader held the portfolio throughout the period covered by the historical data sample.
Step (3) involves arranging the values for profit and loss from the distribution of profit and loss computed in Step (2) in ascending order. A profit and loss can therefore be computed corresponding to any percentile in the distribution so arranged, so that, for example, a CAR value corresponding to a statistical confidence of 95% can be computed by reference to the bottom fifth percentile.
4.2 Credit Risk . In preferred embodiments of the present invention, a trader may make investments in a group'of DBAR contingent claims using a margin loan. In preferred embodiments of the present invention implementing DBAR digital options, an investor may make an investment with a profit and loss scenario comparable to a sale of a digital put or call option and thus have some loss if the option expires "in the money," as discussed in Section 6, below. In preferred embodiments, credit risk may be measured by estimating the amount of possible loss that other traders in the group of contingent claims could suffer owing to the inability of a given trader to repay a margin loan or otherwise cover a loss exposure. For example, a trader may have invested $1 in a given -15ll-state for a group of DBAR contingent claims with $.50 of margin. Assuming a canonical DRF
for this example, if the state later fails to occur, the DRF collects $1 from the trader (ignoring interest) which would require repayment of the'margin loan. As the trader may be unable to repay the margin loan at the required time, the traders with successful trades may potentially not be able to receive the full amounts owing them under the DRF, and may therefore receive payouts lower than those indicated by the finalized returns for a given trading period for the group of contingent claims. Alternatively, the risk of such possible losses due to credit risk may be insured, with the cost of such insurance either borne by the exchange or passed on to the traders: One advantage of the system and method of the present invention is that, in preferred 10-. embodiments,~the amount of credit risk associated with a group of contingent claims can readily be calculated.
In preferred embodiments, the calculation of credit risk for a portfolio of groups of DBAR contingent claims involves computing a credit-capital-at-risk ("CCAR") figure in a manner analogous to the computation of CAR for market risk, as described above.
1 S The computation of CCAR involves the use of data related to the amount of margin used by each trader for each investment in each state for each group of contingent claims in the portfolio, data related to the probability of each trader defaulting on the margin loan (which can typically be obtained from data made available by credit rating agencies, such as Standard and Poors, and data related to the correlation of changes in credit ratings or default probabilities for 20 every pair of traders (which can be obtained, for example, from JP Morgan's CreditMetrics database).
In preferred embodiments, CCAR computations can be made with varying levels of accuracy and reliability. For example, a calculation of CCAR that is substantially accurate but could be improved with more data and computational effort may nevertheless be adequate, 25 depending upon the group of contingent claims and the desires of traders for credit risk related information. The VAR methodology, for example, can be adapted to the computation of CCAR
for a group of DBAR contingent claims, although it is also possible to use MCS
and HS related techniques for such computations. The steps that can be used in a preferred embodiment to compute CCAR using VAR-based, MCS-based, and HS-based methods are described below.
30 4.2.1 CCAR Method for DBAR Continent Claims Using the VAR-based Methodolo~r Step (i) of the VAR-based CCAR methodology involves obtaining, for each trader in a group of DBAR contingent claims, the amount of margin used to make each trade or the amount of potential loss exposure from trades with profit and loss scenarios comparable to sales of options in conventional markets.
Step (ii) involves obtaining data related to the probability of default for each trader who has invested in the groups of DBAR contingent claims. Default probabilities can be obtained from credit rating agencies, from the JP Morgan CreditMetrics database, or from other sources as known to one of skill in the art. In addition to default probabilities, data related to the amount recoverable upow default can be obtained. For example; an AA-rated trader with $1 in margin loans may be able to repay $.80 dollars in the event of default.
Step (iii) involves scaling the standard deviation of returns in units of the invested amounts. This scaling step is described in step (1) of the VAR methodology described above for estimating market risk. The standard deviation of each return, determined according to Step (1) of the VAR methodology previously described, :is scaled by (a) the percentage of margin [or loss exposure] for each investment; (b) the probability of default for the trader;
and (c) the percentage not recoverable in the event of default.
Step (iv) of this VAR-based CCAR methodology involves taking from step (iii) the scaled values for each state for each investment and performing the matrix calculation described in Step (2) above for the VAR methodology for estimating market risk, as described above. In other words, the standard deviations of returns in.units of invested amounts which have been scaled as described in Step (iii) of this CCAR methodology are weighted according to the correlation between each possible pair of states (matrix CS; as described above). The resulting number is a credit-adjusted standard deviation of returns in units of the invested amounts for each trader for each investment- on the portfolio of groups of DBAR contingent claims. For a group of DBAR contingent claims, the standard deviations of returns that have been scaled in this fashion are arranged into a vector whose dimension equals the number of traders.
Step (v) of this VAR-based CCAR methodology involves performing a matrix computation, similar to that performed in Step (S) of the VAR methodology for CAR described above. In this computation, the vector of credit-scaled standard deviations of returns from step (iv) are used to pre- and post-multiply a correlation matrix with rows and columns equal to the number of traders, with 1's along the diagonal, and with the entry at row i and column j containing the statistical correlation of changes in credit ratings described above. The square root of the resulting matrix multiplication is an approximation of the standard deviation of losses, due to default, for all the traders in a group of DBAR contingent claims. This value can be scaled by a number of standard deviations corresponding to a statistical confidence of the credit-related loss not to be exceeded, as discussed above.
In a preferred embodiment, any given trader may be omitted from a CCAR
calculation.
The result is the CCAR facing the given trader due to the credit risk posed by other traders who have invested in a group of DBAR contingent claims. This computation can be made for all groups of DBAR contingent claims in which a trader has a position, and the resulting number can :be weighted by the correlation matrix for the underlying events, Ce, as described in Step (5) for the VAR-based CAR calculation. The result corresponds to the risk of loss posed by the possible defaults of other traders across all the states of all the groups of DBAR
contingent claims in a 10' ~- trader's portfolio.
4.2_.2 CCAR Method for DBAR Continent Claims Using the Monte Carlo Simulation (MCS) Methodology As described above, MCS methods are typically used to simulate representative scenarios for a given group of financial products, compute profits and losses for each representative . . scenario, then analyze the resulting distribution of scenario-profits and losses. The scenarios are designed to be representative in that they are supposed to be based, for instance, on statistical distributions which have been estimated, typically using econometric time series techniques, to have a great degree of relevance for the fixture behavior of the financial products. A preferred embodiment of MCS methods to estimate CCAR for a portfolio of DBAR contingent claims of 20' ' the present invention, involves two steps, as described below.
Step (i) of the MCS methodology is to estimate a statistical distribution of the events of :interest. In computing CCAR for a group of DBAR contingent claims, the events of interest may be both the primary events underlying the groups of DBAR contingent claims, including events that may be fitted to multivariate statistical distributions to compute CAR as described above, as well as the events related to the default of the other investors in the groups of DBAR contingent claims. Thus, in a preferred embodiment, the multivariate statistical distribution to be estimated relates to the market events (e.g., stock price changes, changes in interest rates) underlying the groups of DBAR contingent claims being analyzed as well as the event that the investors in those groups of DBAR contingent claims, grouped by credit rating or classification will be unable to repay margin loans for losing investments.
For example, a multivariate statistical distribution to be estimated might assume that changes in the market events and credit ratings or classifications are jointly normally distributed.
- ~ 54 -Estimating such a distribution would thus entail estimating, for example, the mean changes in the underlying market events (e.g., expected changes in interest rates until the expiration date), the mean changes in credit ratings expected until expiration, the standard deviation for each market event and credit rating change, and a correlation matrix containing all of the pairwise correlations between every pair of events, including market and credit event pairs. Thus, a preferred embodiment of MCS methodology as it applies to CCAR estimation for. groups of DBAR
contingent claims of the present invention typically requires some estimation as to the statistical correlation between market events (e.g., the change in the price of a stock issue) and credit events (e.g., whether an investor rated A- by Standard and Poors is more likely to default or be downgraded if the price of a stock issue goes down rather than up).
It is sometimes difficult to estimate the statistical correlations between market-related events such as changes in stock prices and interest rates, on the one hand, and credit-related events such as counterparty downgrades and defaults, on the other hand. These difficulties can arise due to the relative infrequency of credit downgrades and defaults. The infrequency of such credit-related events may mean that statistical estimates used for MCS
simulation can only be supported with low statistical confidence. In such cases, assumptions can be employed regarding the statistical correlations between the market and credit-related events. For example, it is not uncommon to employ sensitivity analysis with regard to such correlations, i.e., to assume a given correlation between market and credit-related events and then vary the assumption over the entire range of correlations from -1 to 1 to determine the effect on the overall CCAR.
A preferred approach to estimating correlation between events is to use a source of data with regard to credit-related events that does not typically suffer from a lack of statistical frequency. Two methods can be used in this preferred approach. First, data can be obtained that provide greater statistical confidence with regard to credit-related events.
For example, expected default frequency data can be purchased from such companies as KMV
Corporation. These data supply probabilities of default for various parties that can be updated as frequently as daily.
Second, more frequently observed default probabilities can be estimated from market interest rates. For example, data providers such as Bloomberg and Reuters typically provide information on the additional yield investors require for investments in bonds of varying credit ratings, e.g., AAA, AA, A, A-. Other methods are readily available to one skilled in the art to provide estimates regarding default probabilities for various entities. Such estimates can be made as frequently as daily so that it is possible to have greater statistical confidence in the parameters typically needed for MCS, such as the correlation between changes in default probabilities and changes in stock prices, interest rates, and exchange rates.
The estimation of such correlations is illustrated assuming two groups of DBAR
contingent claims of interest, where one group is based upon the closing price of IBM stock in ~ three months, and the other group is based upon the closing yield of the 30-year U.S. Treasury bond.in three months. In this illustration, it is also assumed that the counterparties who have made 'investments on margin in each of the groups can be divided into five distinct credit rating classes. Data on the daily changes in the price of IBM and the bond yield may be readily obtained from such sources as Reuters or Bloomberg. Frequently changing data on the expected default probability of investors can be obtained, for example, from KMV
Corporation, or estimated fi-om interest rate data as described above. As the default probability ranges between 0 and l;~a statistical distribution confined to this interval is chosen for purposes of this illustration.
For example, for purposes of this illustration, it' can be assumed that the expected default probability of the investors follows a logistic distribution and that the joint distribution of changes in IBM stock and the 30-year bond yield follows.a bivariate normal distribution. The p~~eters for.the logistic distribution and the bivariate normal distribution can be estimated using econometric techniques known to one skilled in the art.
Step (ii) of.a MCS technique, as it may be applied to estimating CCAR for groups of DBAR contingent claims, involves the use of the multivariate statistical distributions estimated in Step (i) above in order to simulate the representative scenarios. As described above, such simulations can be performed using methods and software readily available and known to those of skill imthe art. For each simulated scenario, the simulated default rate can be multiplied by the amount of losses an investor faces based upon the simulated market changes and the margin, if any, the investor has used to make losing investments. The product represents an estimated loss rate due to investor defaults. Many such scenarios can be generated so that a resulting distribution of credit-related expected losses can be obtained. The average value of the distribution is the mean loss. The lowest value of the top fifth percentile of the distribution, for example, would correspond to a loss for which a given trader could be 95%
confident would not be exceeded, provided that enough scenarios have been generated to provide a statistically meaningful sample. In preferred embodiments, the selected value in the distribution, corresponding to a desired or adequate confidence level, is used as the CCAR
for the groups of DBAR contingent claims being analyzed.

4.2.3 CCAR Method for DBAR Continent Claims Using the Historical Simulation ("HS'~ Methodology As described above, Historical Simulation (HS) is comparable to MCS for estimating CCAR in that HS relies on representative scenarios in order to compute a distribution of profit and loss for a portfolio of groups of DBAR contingent claim investments.
Rather than relying on simulated scenarios from an estimated multivariate statistical distribution, however, HS uses historical data for the scenarios. In a preferred embodiment, HS methodology for calculating CCAR for.groups of DBAR contingent claims uses three steps, described below.
Step' (i) involves obtaining the same data for the market-related events as described above in the context of CAR. In addition, to use HS to estimate CCAR, historical time series data are also used for credit-related events such as downgrades and defaults. As such data are typically rare, methods described above can be used to obtain more frequently observed data related to credit events: For example, in a preferred embodiment; frequently-observed data on expected default. probabilities can be obtained from KMV Corporation. Other means for obtaining such data are known. to those of skill in the art.
Step (ii) involves using each observation in the historical data from the previous step (i) to compute payouts using the DRF for each group of DBAR contingent claims being analyzed.
The amount of margin to be repaid for the losing trades, or the loss exposure for investments with-prof t and loss scenarios comparable to digital option "sales," can then be multiplied by the expected default probability to use HS to estimate CCAR, so that an expected loss number can be obtained for each investor for each group of contingent claims. These losses can be summed across'the investment by each trader so that, for each historical observation data point, an expected loss amount due to default can be attributed to each trader. The loss amounts can also be summed across all the investors so that a total expected loss amount can be obtained for all of the investors for each historical data point.
Step (iii) involves arranging, in ascending order,.the values of loss amounts summed across the investors for each data point from the previous step (ii). An expected loss amount due to credit-related events can therefore be computed corresponding to any percentile in the distribution so arranged. For example, a CCAR value corresponding to a 95%
statistical confidence level can be computed by reference to 95~' percentile of the loss distribution.
- i 5? -5. LIQUIDITY AND PRICE/QUANTITY RELATIONSHIPS
In the trading of contingent claims, whether in traditional markets or using groups of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention, it is frequently useful to distinguish between the fundamental value of the claim, on the one hand, as determined by market expectations, information, risk aversion and financial holdings of traders, and the deviations from such value due to liquidity variations, on the other hand. For example, the fair fundamental value in the traditional swap market for a five-year UK swap (i.e., swapping fined interest for floating rate payments based on UK LIBOR rates) might be 6.79% with a 2 basis point bid/offer (i.e., 6.77%
receive; 6.81 % pay). A large trader who takes the market's fundamental mid-market valuation of 6.79% as correct or-fair might want to trade a swap for a large amount, such as 750 million pounds. In light of likely liquidity available according to current standards of the traditional market, the large amount of the transaction could reduce the likely offered rate to 6.70%, which is a full 7 basis points lower than the average offer (which is probably applicable to offers of no more than 100 million pounds) and 9 basis points away from the fair mid-market value.
The difference in value between a trader's position at the fair or mid-market value and the value at which the trade can actually be completed, i.e. either the bid or offer, is usually called the liquidity charge. For the illustrative five-year IJK swap, a 1 basis point liquidity charge is approximately equal to 0.04% of the amount traded, so that a liquidity charge of 9 basis points equals approximately 2.7 million pounds. If no new information or other fundamental shocks intrude into or "hit" the market, this liquidity charge to the trader is almost always a permanent transaction charge for liquidity -- one that also must be borne when the trader decides to liquidate .
the large position. Additionally, there is no currently reliable way to predict, in the traditional markets, how the.relationship between price and quantity may deviate from the posted bid and offers, which are usually applicable only to limited or representative amounts. Price and quantity relationships can be highly variable, therefore, due to liquidity variations.
Those relationships can also be non-linear. For instance, it may cost more than twice as~much, in terms of a bid/offer spread, to trade a second position that is only twice as large as a first position.
From the point of view of liquidity and transactions costs, groups of DBAR
contingent claims of the present invention offer advantages compared to traditional markets. In preferred embodiments, the relationship between price (or returns) and quantity invested (i.e., demanded) is determined mathematically by a DRF. In a preferred embodiment using a canonical DRF, the implied probability q; for each state i increases, at a decreasing rate, with the amount invested in that state:
T
q' - T
aq; _ T -T
aT TZ
z 8 qt __2*T_T,.
aT2 T3 aqr BT~.i=~ T 2 T
where T is the total amount invested across all the states of the group of DBAR contingent claims and T; is the amount invested in the state i. As a given the amount gets very.large, the implied probability of that state asymptotically approaches one. The last expression immediately above : shows that there is a transparent relationship, available to all traders, between implied probabilities and the amount invested in states other than a given state i.
The expression shows -that this relationship is negative, i.e., as amounts invested in other states increase, the implied probability for the given state i decreases. Since, in preferred embodiments of the present invention, adding investments to states other than the given state is equivalent to selling the given state in the market, the expression for aq' above shows how, in a preferred embodiment, the aTJ.I xf implied probability for the given state changes as a quantity for that state is up for sale, i.e., what the market's "bid" is for the quantity up for sale. The expression for aq' above shows, in a BT,.
preferred embodiment, how the probability for the given state changes when a given quantity is demanded or desired to be purchased, i.e., what the market's "offer" price is to purchasers of the desired quantity.
In a preferred embodiment, for each set of quantities invested in the defined states of a group of DBAR contingent claims, a set of bid and offer curves is available as a function of the amount invested.
In the groups of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention, there are no bids or offers per se. The mathematical relationships above are provided to illustrate how the systems _ i 59 _ and methods of the present invention can, in the absence of actual bid/offer relationships, provide groups of DBAR contingent claims with some of the functionality of bid/offer relationships.
Economists usually prefer to deal with demand and cross-demand elasticities, which are the percentage changes in prices due to percentage changes in quantity demanded for a given good (demand elasticity) or its substitute (cross-demand elasticity). In preferred embodiments of the systems and methods of the present invention, and using the notation developed above, 09; ~~T~
1-9~
qc T;
~t~OTi _ qt Ti qi The first of the expressions immediately above shows that small percentage changes in the amount invested in state i have a decreasing percentage effect on the implied probability for state i, as state i becomes more likely (i.e., as q; increases to 1). The second expression immediately above shows that a percentage change in the amount invested in a state j other than state i will decrease the implied probability for state i in proportion to the implied probability for the other state j.
In preferred embodiments, in order to effectively "sell" a state, traders need to invest or "buy" complement states, i.e., states other than the one they wish to "sell."
Thus, in a preferred embodiment involving a group of DBAR claims with two states, a "seller" of state 1 will "buy"
state 2, and vice versa. In order to "sell" state 1, state 2 needs to be "bought" in proportion to the ratio of the amount invested in state 2 to the amount invested in state 1. In a state distribution which has more than two states, the "complement" for a given state to be "sold" are all of the other states for the group of DBAR contingent claims. Thus, "selling" one state involves "buying" a mufti-state investment, as described above, for the complement states.
Viewed from this perspective, an implied offer is the resulting effect on implied probabilities from making a small investment in a particular state. Also from this perspective, an implied bid is the effect on implied probabilities from making a small mufti-state investment in complement states. For a given state in a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR contingent claims, the effect of an invested amount on implied probabilities can be stated as follows:
Implied "Bid" = q,.' - (1 ~ ' ) * OT,.
Implied "Offer"= q; + q; * ( 1 - 1 ) * OT,.
T T

where OT; (considered here to be small enough for a first-order approximation) is the amount invested for the "bid" or "offer." These expressions for implied "bid" and implied "offer" can be used for approximate computations. The expressions indicate how possible liquidity effects within a group of DBAR contingent claims can be cast in terms familiar in traditional markets.
In the traditional 'markets, however, there is no ready way to compute such quantities for any given market.
The full liquidity effect -- or liquidity response function -- between twa states in a group of DBAR contingent claims can be expressed as functions of the amounts invested in a given state, T;, and amounts invested in the complement states, denoted T'°;, as follows:
T
Implied,"Bid'' Demand Response qB(~T,) _ ~ T' T,. + T,.' + DT,.
( T,. - ~T,. ) Implied "Offer" Demand Response q ~ (OTj ) - T + OT
T,. + T,. + OT
The implied "bid" demand response function shows the effect on the implied state probability of an investment made to hedge an investment of size OT;. The size of the hedge investment in the complement states is proportional to the ratio of investments in the complement states to the amount of investments in the state or states to be hedged, excluding the investment to be hedged (i.e., the third term in the denominator). The implied "offer" demand response function above shows the effect on the implied state probability from an incremental investment of size OT; in a particular defined state.
n preferred embodiments of systems and methods of the present invention, only the finalized returns for a given trading period are applicable for computing payouts for a group of DBAR contingent claims. Thus, in preferred embodiments, unless the effect of a trade amount on returns is permanent, i.e., persists through the end of a trading period, a group of DBAR
contingent claims imposes no permanent liquidity charge, as the traditional markets typically do.
Accordingly, in preferred embodiments, traders can readily calculate the effect on returns from investments in the DBAR contingent claims, and unless these calculated effects are permanent, they will not affect closing returns and can, therefore, be ignored in appropriate circumstances.
In other words, investing in a preferred embodiment of a group of DBAR
contingent claims does not impose a permanent liquidity charge on traders for exiting and entering the market, as the traditional markets typically do.
-i61-The effect of a large investment may, of course, move infra-trading period returns in a group of DBAR contingent claims as indicated by the previous calculations. In preferred embodiments, these effects could well be counteracted by subsequent investments that move the market back to fair value (in the absence of any change in the fundamental or fair value). In traditional markets, by contrast, there is usually a "toll booth" effect in the sense that a toll or change is usually exacted every time a trader enters and exits the market.
This toll is larger when there is less "traffic" or liquidity and represents a permanent loss to the trader. By contrast, other than an exchange fee, in preferred embodiments of groups of DBAR contingent claims, there is no: such permanent liquidity tax or toll for market entry or exit.
Liquidity effects may be permanent from investments in a group of DBAR
contingent clairris if a'~trader is attempting to make a relatively very large investment near the end of a trading period, such that the market may not have sufficient time to adjust back to fair value.
Thus, in preferred embodiments, there should be an inherent incentive not to hold back large investments until the end of the trading period, thereby providing incentives to make large ~ investments earlier, which is beneficial overall to liquidity and adjustment of returns.
Nonetheless, a trader can readily calculate the effects on returns to a investment which the trader thinks might be permanent (e.g., at the end of the trading period), due to the effect on the market from a large investment amount.
For example, in the two period hedging example (Example 3.1.19) above, it was assumed that the illustrated trader's investments had no material effect on the posted returns, in other words, that this trader was a "price taker." The formula for the hedge trade H
in the second period .pf that-example above reflects this assumption. The following equivalent expression for H takes account of the possibly permanent effect that a large trade investment might have on the closing returns (because, for example, the investment is made very close to the end of the trading period):
P -T+~ + Z'r+~ -2*T+~ *P +PZ +4*P *T+~
H=

where P =cz~ *(1+r,) in the notation used in Example 3.1.19, above, and T~+~ is the total amount invested in period t+1 and T'°~+i is the amount invested in the complement state in period t+1. The expression for H is the quadratic solution which generates a desired payout, as described above but using the present notation. For example, if $1 billion is the total amount, T, invested in trading period 2, then, according to the above expressions, the hedge trade investment assuming a permanent effect on returns is $70.435 million compared to $70.18755 million in Example 3.1.19.
The amount of profit and loss locked-in due to the new hedge is $1.232 million, compared to $1.48077 in Example 3.1.19. The difference represents the liquidity effect, which even in the example where the invested notional is 10% of the total amount invested, is quite reasonable in a market for groups of DBAR contingent claims. There is no ready way to estimate or calculate such liquidity effects in araditional markets.
10' 6. DBAR DIGITAL OPTIONS EXCHANGE
In a preferred embodiment, the DBAR methods and systems of the present invention may be used to implement financial products known as digital options and to facilitate an exchange in such products. A digital option (sometimes also known as a binary option) is a derivative security which pays a fixed amount should specified conditions be met (such:
as the price of a . stock exceeding a given level or "strike" price} at the expiration date. If the specified conditions are met; a digital option is often characterized as finishing "in the money."
A digital call option, for.example, would pay a fixed amount of currency, say one dollar; should the value of the underlying security, index, or variable upon which the option is based expire at or above the strike price of the call option. Similarly, a digital put option would: pay a fixed amount of currency should the value of the underlying security, index or variable be at or below the strike price of the put option. A spread of either digital call or put options would pay a fixed amount should the underlying value expire at or between the strike prices. A strip of digital options would pay out fixed ratios should the underlying expire between two sets of strike prices.
Graphically; digital calls, puts, spreads, and strips can have simple representations:
-11C~3-Table 6Ø1 - Digital Call Pays Table 6Ø2 - Digital Put Pays Kv S Table 6.0:3 - Di 'petal Spread Pays Table 6Ø4 - Digital Striu Pays K' K°
Kl ~2 K3 As depicted in Tables 6Ø1, 6Ø2, 6Ø3, and 6Ø4, the strike prices for the respective options are marked using familiar options notation where the subscript "c" indicates a call, the subscript "p"
indicates a put, the. subscript "s" indicates "spread," and the superscripts "1" and "u" indicate lower and upper strikes, respectively.
A difference between digital options, which are frequently transacted in the OTC foreign currency options markets, and traditional options such as the equity options, which trade on the Chicago Board Options Exchange ("OBOE"), is that digital options have payouts which do not vary with the extent to which the underlying asset, index, or variable ("underlying") finishes in or out of the money. For example, a digital call option at a strike price for the underlying stock at 50 would pay the same amount if, at the fulfillment of all of the termination criteria, the underlying stock price was 51, 60, 75 or any other value at or above 50. In this sense, digital options represent the academic foundations of options theory, since traditional equity options could in theory be replicated from a portfolio of digital spread options whose strike prices are set to provide vanishingly small spreads. (In fact, a "butterfly spread" of the traditional options yields a digital option spread as the strike prices of the traditional options are allowed to converge.) As can be seen from Tables 6Ø1, 6Ø2, 6.0:3, and 6Ø4, digital options can be constructed from digital option spreads.
The methods and systems of the present invention can be used to create a derivatives market for digital options spreads. In other words, each investment in a state of a mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive set of states of a group of DBAR
contingent claims can be considered to correspond to either a digital call spread or a digital put spread. Since digital spreads can readily and accurately be used to replicate digital options, and since digital options are known, traded and processed in the existing markets, DBAR methods can therefore be represented effectively as a market for digital options - that is, a DBAR
digital options market.
6.1 Representation of Di 'Options as DBAR Contingent Claims One advantage of the digital options representation of DBAR contingent claims is that the trader interface of a DBAR digital options exchange (a "DBAR DOE") can be presented in a format familiar to traders, even though the underlying DBAR market structure is quite novel and different from traditional securities and derivatives markets. For example, the main trader interface for a DBAR digital options exchange, in a preferred embodiment, could have the following features:

Table 6.1.1 MSFT Di 't~ al Options CALLS PUT

TRIKE IND IND OFFERIND PAYOUT IND IND OFFERIND PAYOUT
BID BID

3 0.938 0.940 1.0641 0.059 0.061 16.599 4 0.723 0.724 1.381 0.275 0.277 3.619 0:439 0.440 2.270 0.559 0.5601 1.786 6 0.2241 0.224 4.458 0.775 0.775 1.289 7 0.:101 0.101 9.826 0.89810.898 1.113 0.043 0.043 123.2456 0.95690.9570 1.045 The illustrative interface of Table 6.1.1 contains hypothetical market information on DBAR
5 digital options on Microsoft stock ("MSFT") for a given expiration date. For example, an investor who, desires a payout if MSFT stock closes higher than 50 at the expiration or observation date will need to "pay the offer" of $.4408 per dollar of payout.
Such an offer is "indicative" (abbreviated "IND") since the underlying DBAR distribution --that is, the implied probability that a state or set of states will occur -- may change during the trading period. In a preferred embodiment, the bid/offer spreads presented in Table 6.1.1 are presented in the following manner.. The "offer" side in the market reflects the implied probability that underlying value of the stock (in this example MSFT) will finish "in the money." The "bid" side in the market is the "price" at which a claim can be "sold" including the transaction fee. (In this context, the term "sold" reflects the use of the systems and methods of the present invention to implement investment profit and loss scenarios comparable to "sales" of digital options, discussed in detail below.) The amount in each "offer" cell is greater than the amount in the corresponding "bid" cell. 'The bid/offer quotations for these digital option representations of DBAR contingent claims are presented as percentages of (or implied probabilities for) a one dollar indicative payout.
The illustrative quotations in Table 6.1.1 can be derived as follows. First the payout for a given investment is computed assuming a 10 basis point transaction fee. This payout is equal to the sum of all investments less 10 basis points, divided by the sum of the investments over the range of states corresponding to the digital option. Taking the inverse of this quantity gives the offer side of the market in "price" terms. Performing the same calculation but this time adding 10 basis points to the total investment gives the bid side of the market.
- 1~6 -In another preferred embodiment, transaction fees are assessed as a percentage of payouts, rather than as a function of invested amounts. Thus, the offer (bid) side of the market for a given digital option could be, for example, (a) the amount invested over the range of states comprising the digital option , (b) plus (minus) the fee (e.g., 10 basis points) multiplied by the total invested for all of the defined states, (c) divided by the total invested for all of the defined states. An advantage of computing fees based upon the payout is that the bid/offer spreads as a percentage of "price" would be different depending upon the strike price of the underlying, with strikes that are less likely to be "in the money" having a higher percentage fee. Other embodiments in which the exchange or transaction fees, for example, depend on the time of trade 10- to provide incentives for traders to trade early or to trade certain strikes, or otherwise reflect liquidity conditions in the contract, are apparent to those of skill in the art.
As explained in detail below, in preferred embodiments of the systems and methods of the present invention, traders or investors can buy and "sell" DBAR contingent claims that are represented and behave like digital option puts, calls, spreads, and strips using conditional or i 5 "limit" orders. In addition, these digital options can be processed using existing technological infrastructure in place at current financial institutions. For example, Sungard, Inc., has a large subscriber base to many off the-shelf programs which are capable of valuing, measuring the risk, clearing, and settling digital options. Furthermore, some of the newer middleware protocols such as FINXML (see www.finxml:org) apparently are able to handle digital options and others will 2f probably follow shortly (e:g., FPML). In addition, the transaction costs of a digital options exchange using the methods and systems of the present invention can be represented in a manner consistent with the conventional markets, i.e., in terms of bid/offer spreads.
6.2 Construction of Di ~~Options Using DBAR Methods and S sy terns The methods of multistate trading of DBAR contingent claims previously disclosed can 25 be used to implement investment in a group of DBAR contingent claims that behave like a digital option. In particular, and in a preferred embodiment, this can be accomplished by allocating an investment, using the multistate methods previously disclosed, in such a manner that the same payout is received from the investment should the option expire "in-the-money", e.g., above the strike price of the underlying for a call option and below the strike price of the underlying for a 30 put. In a preferred embodiment, the multistate methods used to allocate the investment need not be made apparent to traders. In such an embodiment, the DBAR methods and systems of the present invention could effectively operate "behind the scenes" to improve the quality of the market without materially changing interfaces and trading screens commonly used by traders.
This may be illustrated by considering the DBAR construction of the MSFT
Digital Options market activity as represented to the user in Table 6.1.1. For purposes of this illustration, it is assumed that the market "prices" or implied probabilities for the digital put and call options as displayed in Table 6.1.1 result from $100 million in investments. The DBAR
states and allocated investrrients that construct these "prices" are then:
Table 6.2.1 tates tate tate Investments Prob (0, 30] 0.060238$ 6,023,869.94 30, 40] 0.216067$ 21,606,756.78 (40,50] 0.283320$ 28,332,029.61 50, 60] 0.216067$ 21,606, 766.30 (60, 70] ~ 0.122543$ 12,254,324.67 (70, 80] 0.058743$ 5,874,363.31 (80, ~) 0.043018$ 4,301,889.39 In Table 6.2.1, the notation (x, y] is used to indicate a single state part of a set of mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive states which excludes x and includes y on the interval.
(For purposes of this specification a convention is adopted for puts, calls, and spreads which is consistent with the internal representation of the states. For example; a put and a call both struck at 50: cannot both be paid out if the underlying asset, index or variable expires exactly at 50: To address this issue, the following convention could be adopted: calls exclude the strike 15. price, puts include the strike price, and spreads exclude the lower and include the upper strike price. This convention, for example, would be consistent with internal states that are exclusive on the lower boundary and inclusive on the upper boundary. Another preferred convention would have calls including the strike price and puts excluding the strike price, so that the representation of the states would be inclusive on the lower boundary and exclusive on the upper.
In any event, related conventions exist in traditional markets. For example, consider the situation of a traditional foreign exchange options dealer who sells an "at the money"
digital and an "at the money" put, with strike price of 100. Each is equally likely to expire "in the money," so for every $1.00 in payout, the dealer should collect $.50.. If the dealer has sold a $1.00 digital call and put, and has therefore collected a total of $1.00 in premium, then if the underlying expires exactly at 100, a discontinuous payout of $2.00 is owed. Hence, in a preferred embodiment of - 16~ -the present invention, conventions such as those described above or similar methods may be adopted to avoid such discontinuities.) A digital call or put may be constructed with DBAR methods of the present invention by using the multistate allocation algorithms previously disclosed. In a preferred embodiment, the construction of a digital option involves allocating the amount to be invested across the constituent states over which the digital option is "in-the-money" (e.g., above the strike for a call, below the strike for a put) in a manner such that the same payout is obtained regardless of which state occurs among the "in the money" constituent states. This is accomplished by allocating the amount invested in the digital option in proportion to the then-existing investments over the range of constituent states for which the option is "in the money." For example, for an additional $1,000,000 investment a digital call struck at 50 from the investments illustrated in Table 6.2.1, the construction of the trade using multistate allocation methods is:
Table 6.2.2 Internal $ 1,000,000.00 States (0, 30]

(30, 40]

(40,50]

(50, 60) $ 490,646.45 (60, 70] $ 278,271.20 (70, 80] $ 133,395.04 (80, ~] $ 97,687.30 As other traders subsequently make investments, the distribution of investments across the states comprising the digital option may change, and may therefore require that the.multistate investments be reallocated so that, for each digital option, the payout is the same for any of its constituent "in :the money" states, regardless of which of these constituent states. occurs after the fulfillment of all of the termination criteria, and is zero for any of the other states. When the investments have been allocated or reallocated so that this payout scenario occurs, the group of investments or cpntract is said to be in equilibrium. A further detailed description of the allocation methods which can be used to achieve this equilibrium is provided in connection with the description of FIGS. 13-14.
6.3 Di 'tp~ al Option Spreads In a preferred embodiment, a digital option spread trade may be offered to investors which simultaneously execute a buy and a "sell" (in the synthetic or replicated sense of the term, - 1~~ -as described below) of a digital call or put option. An investment in such a spread would have the same payout should the underlying outcome expire at any value between the lower and upper strike prices in the spread. If the spread covers one state, then the investment is comparable to an investment in a DBAR contingent claim for that one state. If the spread covers more than one constituent state, in a preferred embodiment the investment is allocated using the multistate investment method previously described so that, regardless of which state occurs among the states included in the spread trade, the investor receives the same payout.
6.4 Digital Option Strips Traders in the derivatives markets commonly trade related groups of futures or options contracts in desired ratios in order to accomplish some desired purpose. For example, it is not uncommon for traders of L1BOR based interest rate futures on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange ("CME") to execute simultaneously a group of futures with different expiration dates covering a -'- number of years. Such a group, which is commonly termed a "strip," is typically traded to hedge another position which can be effectively approximated with a strip whose constituent contracts are executed in target relative ratios. For example, a strip of LIBOR-based interest rate futures may be used to approximate the risk inherent of an interest rate swap of the same maturity as the latest contract expiration date in the strip.
In a preferred embodiment, the DBAR methods of.the present invention can be used to allow traders to construct strips of digital options and digital option spreads whose relative payout ratios, should each option expire in the money, are equal to the ratios specified by the trader. For example, a trader may desire to invest in a strip consisting of the S0, 60, 70, and 80 digital call options on MSFT, as illustrated in Table 6.1.1. Furthermore, and again as an illustrative example, the trader may desire that the payout ratios, should each option expire in the money, be in the following relative ratio: 1:2:3:4. Thus, should the underlying price of MSFT at ~ the expiration date (when the event outcome is observed) be equal to 65, both the 50 and 60 strike digital options are in the money. Since the trader desires that the 60 strike digital call option pay out twice as much as the 50 strike digital call option, a multistate allocation algorithm, as previously disclosed and described in detail, can be used dynamically to reallocate the trader's investments across the states over which these options are in the money (SO
and above, and 60 and above, respectively) in such a way as to generate final payouts which conform to the indicated ratio of 1:2. As previously disclosed, the multistate allocation steps may be performed each time new investments are added during the trading period, and a final multistate allocation may be performed after the trading period has expired.
6.5 Multistate Allocation Al~~orithm for Replicating "Sell" Trades In a preferred embodiment of a digital options exchange using DBAR methods and systems of the present invention, traders are able to make investments in DBAR
contingent claims which correspond to purchases of digital options. Since DBAR methods are inherently demand-based -- i.e., a DBAR exchange or market fimctions without traditional sellers -- an advantage of the multistate allocation methods of the present invention is the ability to generate scenarios of profits and losses ("P&L") comparable to the PBcL scenarios obtained from selling digital options, spreads, and strips in traditional, non-DBAR markets without traditional sellers or order-matching.
In traditional markets, the act of selling a digital option, spread, or strip means that the investor (in the case of a sale, a seller) receives the cost of the option, or premium, if the option expires worthless or out of the money. Thus, if the option expires out of the money, the investor/seller's profit is the premium. Should the option expire in the money, however, the investor/seller incurs a net liability.equal to the digital option payout less the premium received.
In this situation, the investor/seller's net loss is the payout less the premium received for selling the option, or the notional payout less the premium. Selling an option, which is equivalent in many respects to the activity of selling insurance, is potentially quite risky, given the large contingent liabilities potentially involved. Nonetheless, option selling is commonplace in conventional, non-DBAR markets.
As indicated above, an advantage of the digital options representation of the DBAR
methods of the present invention is the presentation of an interface which displays bids and offers and therefore, by design, allows users to make investments in sets of DBAR
contingent claims whose P&L scenarios are comparable to those from traditional "sales" as well as purchases of digital calls, puts, spreads, and strips. Specifically in this context, "selling" entails the ability to achieve a profit and loss profile which is analogous to that achieved by sellers of digital options instruments in non-DBAR markets, i.e., achieving a profit equal to the premium should the digital option expire out of the money, and suffering a net loss equal to the digital option payout (or the notional) less the premium received should the digital option expire in the money.
In a preferred embodiment of a digital options exchange using the DBAR
contingent claims methods and systems of the present invention, the mechanics of "selling" involves converting such '.'sell" orders to complementary buy orders. Thus, a sale of the MSFT digital put options with strike price equal to 50, would be converted, in a preferred DBAR
DOE
embodiment, to a complementary purchase of the 50 strike digital call options.
A detailed explanation of the conversion process of a "sale" to a complementary buy order is provided in connection with the description of FIG. 15.
The complementary conversion of DBAR DOE "sales" to buys is facilitated by interpreting the amount to be "sold" in a manner which is somewhat different from the amount to be bought for a DBAR DOE buy order. In a preferred embodiment, when a trader specifies an amount in an order to be "sold," the amount is interpreted as the total amount of loss that the ' trader will suffer should the digital option, spread, or strip sold expire in the money. As indicated above, the total amount lost or net loss is equal to the notional payout less the premium from the sale. . For example, if the trader "sells" $1,000,000 of the MSFT digital put struck at 50, if the price of MSFT at expiration is'S0 or below, then the trader will lose $1,000,000.
Correspondingly, in a preferred embodiment of the present invention, the order amount specified in a DBAR DOE "sell" order is interpreted as the net amount lost should the option,. strip; or spread sold expire in the money. In conventional options markets, the amount would be interpreted and termed a "notional" or "notional amount" less the premium received, since the actual amount lost should the option expire in the money is the payout, or notional, less the premium received. By contrast, the amount of a buy order, in a preferred DBAR
DOE
embodiment, is interpreted as the amount to be.invested over the range of defined states which will generate the payout shape or profile expected by the trader. The amount to be invested is 'therefore equivalent to the option "premium" in conventional options markets.
Thus, in preferred embodiments of the present invention, for DBAR DOE buy orders, the order amount or premium is known and specified by the trader, and the contingent gain or payout should the option purchased finish in the money is not known until after all trading has ceased, the final equilibrium contingent claim "prices" or implied probabilities are calculated and any other termination criteria are fulfilled. By contrast, for a "sell" order in a preferred DBAR DOE
embodiment of the present invention, the amount specified in the order is the specified net loss (equal~to the notional less the premium) which represents the contingent loss should the option expire in the money. Thus, in a preferred embodiment, the amount of a buy order is interpreted as an investment amount or premium which generates an uncertain payout until all predetermined termination criteria have been met; and the amount of a "sell" order is interpreted as a certain net loss should the option expire in the money corresponding to an investment amount or premium that remains uncertain until all predetermined termination criteria have been met. In other words, in a DBAR DOE preferred embodiment, buy orders are for "premium" while "sell"
orders are for net loss should the option expire in the money.
A relatively simple example illustrates the process, in a preferred embodiment of the present invention, of converting a "sale" of a DBAR digital option, strip, or spread to a complementary buy and the meaning of interpreting the amount of a buy order and "sell" order differently. Referring the MSFT example illustrated in Table 6.1.1 and Table 6.2.1 above, assume that a trader has placed a market order (conditional or limit orders are described in detail below) to "selY' the digital put with strike price equal to 50. Ignoring transaction costs, the "price" of the f0 digital put option is equal to the sum of the implied state probabilities spanning the states where the option is in the money (i.e., (0,30],(30,40], and (40,50}) and is approximately.
0.5596266. When the 50 put is in the money, the 50 call is out of the money and vice versa.
Accordingly, the 50 digital call is "complementary" to the 50 digital put.
Thus, "selling" the 50 digital put for. a given amount is equivalent in a preferred embodiment to investing that amount in the complementary call, and that amount is the net loss that would be suffered should the 50 digital put expire in the money (i.e., 50 and below). For example, if a trader places a market order to "self' 1,000,000 value units of the 50 strike digital put, this 1,000,000 value units are interpreted as the net loss if the digital put option expires in the money, i.e., it corresponds to the notional payout loss plus the premium received from the "sale."
In preferred embodiments of the present investment, the 1,000,000 value units to be "sold" are treated as invested in the complementary 50-strike digital call, and therefore are allocated according to the multistate allocation algorithm described in connection with the description of FIG. 13. The 1,000,000 value units are allocated in proportion to the value units previously allocated to the range of states comprising the 50-strike digital call, as indicated in Table 6.2.2 above. Should the digital put expire in the money, the trader "selling" the digital put loses 1,000,000 value units, i.e., the trader loses the payout or notional less the premium. Should the digital put finish out of the money, the trader will receive a payout approximately equal to 2,242,583.42 value units (computed by taking the total amount of value units invested, or 101,000,000, dividing by the new total invested in each state above 50 where the digital put. is out of the money, and multiplying by the corresponding state investment). The payout is the same regardless of which state above 50 occurs upon fulfillment of the termination criteria, i.e., the multistate allocation has achieved the desired payout profile for a digital option. In this illustration, the "sell" of the put will profit by 1,242,583.42 should the option sold expire out of the money. This profit is equivalent to the premium "sold." On the other hand, to achieve a net loss of 1,000,000 value units from a payout of 2,242,583.42, the premium is set at 1,242,583.42 S value units.
The trader who "sells" in a preferred embodiment of a DBAR DOE specifies an amount that is the payout or notional to be sold less the premium to be received, and not the profit or premium to be made should the option expire out of the money. By specifying the payout or notional "sold" less the premium, this amount can be used directly as the amount to be invested in the complementary option, strip, or spread. Thus, in a preferred-embodiment, a DBAR
digital options exchange can replicate or synthesize the equivalent of trades involving the sale of option payouts or notional (less the premium received) in the traditional market.
In another preferred embodiment, an investor may be able to specify the amount of premium to be "sold." To illustrate this embodiment, quantity of premium to be "sold" can be assigned to the variable-x. An investment of quantity y on the states complementary to the range of states being "sold" is related to the premium x in the following manner:
Y
-y=x 1-p where p is the final equilibrium "price", including the "sale" x (and the complementary investment y) of the option being "sold." Rearranging this expression yields the amount of the complementary buy investment y that must be made to effect the "sale" of the premium x:
y-x* (1-P) P
From this it can be seen that, given an amount of premium x that is desired to be "sold," the complementary investment that must be bought on the complement states in order for the trader . to receive the premium x, should the option "sold" expire out of the money, is a function of the price of the option being "sold." Since the price of the option being "sold"
can be expected to vary during the trading period, in a preferred embodiment of a DBAR DOE of the present invention, the amount y required to be invested in the complementary state as a buy order can also be expected to vary during the trading period.
- ll 74~ -In a preferred embodiment, traders may specify an amount of notional less the premium to be "sold" as denoted by the variable y. Traders may then specify a limit order "price" (see Section 6.8 below for discussion of limit orders) such that, by the previous equation relating y to x, a trader may indirectly specify a minimum value of x with the specified limit order "price,"

which may be substituted for p in the preceding equation. In another preferred embodiment, an order..containing iteratively revised y amounts, as "prices" change during the trading period are submitted. In another preferred embodiment, recalculation of equilibrium "prices" with these revised y amounts is likely to lead to a convergence of the y amounts in equilibrium. In this embodiment an iterative procedure may be employed to seek out the complementary buy 1D arriounts that must be invested on the option, strip, or spread complementary to the range of states comprising the option being "sold" in order to replicate the desired premium that the trader desired to "sell." This embodiment is useful since it aims to make the act of "selling" in a DBAR
DOE more similar to the traditional derivatives markets.
It should be emphasized that the traditional markets differ from the systems and methods of the present invention in as least one fundamental respect. In traditional markets, the sale of an option requires a seller who is willing to sell the:option at an agreed-upon price. An exchange of DBAR contingent claims of the present invention, in contrast, does not require or involve such sellers. Rather, appropriate investments may be made (or bought) in contingent claims in appropriate states so that the payout to the investor is the same as if the claim, in a traditional market, had been sold. In particular, using the methods and systems of the present invention, the amounts to be invested in various states can be calculated so that the payout profile replicates the payout,profile of a sale of a digital option in a traditional market, but without the need for a seller. These steps are described in detail in connection with FIG. 15.
6.6 Clearing and Settlement In a preferred embodiment of a digital options exchange using the DBAR
contingent claims systems and methods of the present invention, all types of positions may be processed as digital options. This is because at fixing (i.e., the finalization of contingent claim "prices" or implied probabilities at the termination of the trading period or other fulfillment of all of the termination criteria) the profit and loss expectations of all positions in the DEAR exchange are, from the trader's perspective, comparable to if not the same as the profit and loss expectations of standard digital options commonly traded in the OTC markets, such as the foreign exchange options market (but without the presence of actual sellers, who are needed on traditional options exchanges or in traditional OTC derivatives markets). The contingent claims in a DBAR DOE of the present invention, once finalized at the end of a trading period, may therefore be processed as digital options or combinations of digital options. For example, a MSFT
digital optiorn call spread with a lower strike of 40 and upper sh ike of 60 could be processed as a purchase of the lower strike digital option and a sale of the upper strike digital option.
There are many vendors of back office software that can readily handle the processing of digital options. For example, Sungard, Inc., produces a variety of mature software systems for the processing of derivatives securities, including digital options.
Furthermore, in-house.
derivatives systems currently in use at major banks have basic digital options capability. Since digital options .are commonly encountered instruments, many of the middleware initiatives currently underway e.g., FINXML, will likely incorporate a standard protocol for handling digital options. Therefore, an advantage of a preferred embodiment of the DBA,R DOE of the present invention is the ability to integrate with and otherwise use existing teclW
ology for such an exchange.
6.7 Contract Initialization Another advantage of the systems.and methods of the present invention is that, as previously noted, digital options positions can be represented internally as composite trades.
Composite trades are useful since they help assure that an equilibrium distribution of investments among the states can be achieved. In preferred embodiments, digital option and spreading activity will contribute to an equilibrium distribution. Thus, in preferred embodiments, indicative distributions may be used to initialize trading at the beginning of the trading period.
Iwa preferred embodiment; these initial distributions may be represented as investments or opening orders in each of the defined states making up the contract or in the group of DBAR
contingent claims being traded in the auction. Since these investments need not be actual trader invesirnents, they may be reallocated among the defined states as actual trading occurs, so long as the initial investments do not change the implicit probabilities of the states resulting from actual investments. In a preferred embodiment, the reallocation of initial investments is performed gradually so as to maximize the stability of.digital call and put "prices" (and spreads), as viewed by investors. By the end of the trading period, all of the initial investments may be reallocated in proportion to the investments in each of the defined states made by actual traders.
The reallocation process may be represented as a composite trade that has a same payout irrespective of which of the defined states occurs. In preferred embodiments the initial distribution can be chosen using current market indications from the traditional markets to provide guidance for traders, e.g., options prices from traditional option markets can be used to calculate a traditional market consensus probability distribution, using for example, the well-known technique of Breeden and Litzenberger. Other reasonable initial and indicative distributions could be used. Alternatively, in a preferred embodiment, initialization can be performed in such a manner that each defined state is initialized with a very small amount, distributed equally among each of the defined states. For example, each of the defined states could be initialized with 10'~ value units. Initialization in this manner is designed to start each state -with a quantity that is very small, distributed so as to provide a very small amount of information regarding the implied probability of each defined state. Other initialization methods .
of the defined states are,possible and could be implemented by one of skill in the art.
6.8 . Conditional Investments, or Limit Orders - w In a preferred embodiment of the system and methods of the present invention, traders may be able to make investments which are only binding if a certain "price" or implied probability for a given state or digital option (or strip, spread, etc.) is achieved. In this context, the word "price;" is used for convenience arid familiarity and, in the systems and methods of the present invention, reflects the implied probability of the occurrence of the set of states corresponding to an option -- i.e., the implied probability that the option expires "in the money."
For instance, in the example reflected in Table 6.2.1; a trader may wish to make an investment in the MSFT digital call options with strike price of 50, but may desire that such an investment actually be made only if the final equilibrium "price" or implied probability is .42 or less. Such a conditional investment, which is conditional upon the final equilibrium "price" for the digital option, is sometimes referred to (in conventional markets) as a "limit order."
Limit orders are popular in traditional markets since they provide the means for investors to execute a trade at "their price" or better. Of course, there is no guarantee that such a limit order -- which may be placed significantly away from the current market price -- will in fact be executed. Thus, in traditional markets, limit orders provide the means to control the price at which a trade is executed, without the trader having to monitor the market continuously. In the systems and method of the present invention, limit orders provide a way for investors to control the likelihood that their orders will be executed at their preferred "prices" (or better), also without having continuously to' monitor the market.

In a preferred embodiment of a DBAR DOE, traders are permitted to buy and sell digital call and put options, digital spreads, and digital strips with limit "prices"
attached. The limit "price" indicates that a trader desires that his trade be executed at that indicated limit "price" --actually the implied probability that the option will expire in the money --"or better." In the case S of a purchase of a digital option, "better" means at the indicated limit "price" implied probability or lower (i.e., purchasing not higher than the indicated limit "price"). In the case of a "sale" of a DBAR digital option, "better" means at the indicated limit "price" (implied probability) or higher (i.e., selling not lower than the indicated limit "price").
A benefit of a preferred embodiment of a DBAR DOE of the present invention which includes conditional investments or limit orders is that the placing of limit orders is a well-known mechanism in the financial markets. By allowing traders and investors to interact with a DBAR
DOE of the present invention using limit orders, more liquidity should flow into the DBAR DOE
because of the familiarity of the mechanism, even though the underlying architecture of the DBAR DOE is different from the underlying architecture of other financial markets.
The present invention also includes novel methods and systems for computing the equilibrium "prices" or implied probabilities, in the presence.of limit orders, of DBAR
contingent claims in the various states. These methods and systems can be used to arrive at an equilibrium exclusively in the presence of limit orders, exclusively in the presence of market orders, and in the presence of both. In a preferred embodiment, the.steps to compute a DBAR
20' DOE equilibrium for a group of contingent claims including at least one limit order are summarized as follows:
6.8(1) Convert all "sale" orders to complementary buy orders. This is achieved by (i) identifying the states complementary to the states being sold; (ii) using the amount "sold" as the amount to be invested in the complementary states, and; and (iii) for ' limit orders, adjusting the limit "price" to one minus the original limit "price."
6.8(2) Group the limit orders by placing all of the limit orders which span or comprise the same range of defined states into the same group. Sort each group from the best (highest "price" buy) to the worst (lowest "price" buy). All orders may be processed as buys since any "sales" have previously been converted to complementary buys. For example, in the context of the MSFT Digital Options illustrated in Table 6.2.1, there would be separate groups for the 30 digital calls, the 30 digital puts, the 40 digital calls, the 40 digital puts, etc. In addition, separate groups are made for each spread or strip that spans or comprises a distinct set of defined states.
6.8(3) Initialize the contract or group of DBAR contingent claim'. This may be done, in a preferred embodiment; by allocating minimal quantities of value units uniformly S across the entire distribution of defined states so that each defined state has a non-zero quantity of value units.
6.8(4) For all limit orders, adjust the limit "prices" of such orders by subtracting from each limit order the order, transaction or exchange fees for the respective contingent claims.
- . 6.8(5) With all orders broken into minimal size unit lots (e.g., one dollar or other small value unit for the group of DBAR contingent claims), identify one order from a group that has a limit "price"better than the current equilibrium "price" for the option, spread, or strip specified in the order.
6.8(6) With the identified order, find the maximum number of additional unit lots 1 S ("lots") than can be invested such that the limit "price" is no worse than the equilibrium "price" with the chosen maximum number of unit lots added. The maximum number of lots can be found by (i) using the method of binary search, as described in detail below, (ii) trial addition of those lots to already-invested amounts and (iii) recalculating the equilibrium iteratively.
6.8(7) Identify any orders which have limit "prices" worse than the current calculated equilibrium "prices" for the contract or group of DBAR contingent claims. Pick such an order with the worst limit "price'' from the group containing the order.
Remove the minimum quantity of unit lots required so that the order's limit "price" is no longer worse than the equilibrium "price" calculated when the unit lots are removed. The number of lots to be removed can be found by (i) using the method of binary search, as described in detail below, (ii) trial subtraction of those lots from already invested amounts and (iii) recalculating the equilibrium iteratively.
6.8(8) Repeat steps 6.8(5) to 6.8(7). Terminate those steps when no fiu-ther additions or removals are necessary.
- g 79 -6.8(9) Optionally, publish the equilibrium from step 6.8(8) both during the trading period and the final equilibrium at the end of the trading period. The calculation during the trading period is performed "as i~' the trading period were to end at the moment the calculation is performed. All prices resulting from the equilibrium computation are considered mid-market prices, i.e., they do not include the bid and offer spreads owing to transaction fees. Published offer (bid) "prices"
are set equal to the mid-market equilibrium "prices" plus (minus) the fee.
In a preferred embodiment, the preceding steps 6.8(1) to 6.8(8) and optionally step 6.8(9) are performed each time the set of orders during the trading or auction period changes. For example, when a new order is submitted or an existing order is cancelled (or otherwise modified) the set of orders changes, steps 6.8(1) to 6.8(8) (and optionally step 6.8(9)) would need to be repeated.
The preceding steps result in an equilibrium of the DBAR contingent clairris and executable orders which satisfy typical trader expectations for a market for digital options:
(1) At least some buy ("sell") orders-with a limit "price" greater (less) than or equal to the equilibrium "price" for the given option, spread or strip are executed or "filled."
(2) No buy ("sell") orders with limit "prices" less (greater) than the equilibrium "price" for the given option, spread or strip are executed.
' (3) The total amount of executed lots equals the total amount invested across the distribution of defined states.
(4) The ratio of payouts should each constituent state of a given option, spread, or strike occur is as specified by the trader, (including equal payouts in the case of digital options), within a tolerable degree of deviation.
(5) Conversion of filled limit orders to customer orders for the respective filled quantities and recalculating the equilibrium does not materially change the equilibrium.
(6) Adding one or more lots to any of the filled limit orders converted to market orders in step (5) and recalculating of the equilibrium "prices" results in "prices"
which violate the limit "price" of the order to which the lot was added (i.e., no more lots can be "squeaked in" without forcing market prices to go above the limit "prices" of buy orders or below the limit "prices" of sell orders).
- ~ 80 -The following example illustrates the operation of a preferred embodiment of a DBAR
DOE of the present invention exclusively with limit orders. It is anticipated that a DBAR DOE
will operate and process both limit and non-limit or market orders. As apparent to a person of skill in the art, if a DBAR DOE can operate with only limit orders, it can also operate with both lirriit orders and market orders.
Like earlier examples, this example is also based on digital options derived from the price .
of MSFT' stock. To reduce the complexity of the example, it is assumed, for purposes of illustration, that there are illustrative purposes, only three strike prices:
$30, $50, and $80.
Table 6.8.1 Buy Orders 0 calls 0 calls 80 calls Limit QuantitLimit Quanti Limit Quanti "Price "Price" "Price"

0.82 10000 0.43 10000 0.1 10000 0.835 10000 0.47 10000 0.14 10000 0.84 10000 0.5 10000 80 puts 0 puts 0 puts 0.88 10000 0.5 10000 0.16 10000 0.9 10000 0.52 10000 0.17 10000 0.92 10000 0.54 10000 Table 6.8.2 "Sell" Orders 0 calls 0 calls 80 calls Limit QuantitLimit Quanti Limit Quanti "Price' "Price" "Price"

0.81 5000 0.42 10000 0.11 10000 ' 0.44 10000 0.12 10000 80 puts 0 puts 30 puts 0.9 20000 0.45 10000 0.15 5000 0.50 10000 0.16 10000 - 18ll -The quantities entered in the "Sell Orders" table, Table 6.8.2, are the net loss amounts which the trader is risking should the option "sold" expire in the money, i.e., they are equal to the notional less the premium received from the sale, as discussed above.
S (i) According to step 6.8(1) of the limit order methodology described above, the "sale" orders are first converted to buy orders. This involves switching the contingent claim "sold" to a buy of the complementary contingent claim and creating a new limit "price" for the converted order equal to one minus the limit "price" of the sale. Converting the "sell" orders in Table 6.8.2 therefore yields the following converted buy orders:
Table 6.8.3 "Sale" Orders Converted to Buy Orders 0 puts 0 puts 0 puts Limit Quanti Limit QuantityLimit Quantity "Price' "Price" "Price 0.19 5000 0.58 10000 0.89 10000 0.56 10000 0.88 10000 80 calls 0 calls 0 calls 0.1 20000 0.55 10000 0.85 5000 0.50 10000 0.84 10000 1 S (ii) According to step 6.8(2), the orders are then placed into groupings based upon the range of states which each underlying digital option comprises or spans. The groupings for this illustration therefore are: 30 calls, 50 calls, calls, 30 puts, 50 puts, and 80 puts (iii) In this illustrative example, the initial liquidity in each of the defined states is set at one value unit.
(iv) According to step 6.8(4), the orders are arranged from worst "price"
(lowest for buys) to best "price" (highest for buys). Then, the limit "prices"
are adjusted for the effect of transaction or exchange costs. Assuming that the transaction fee for each order is S basis points (.0005 value units), then .0005 is subtracted from each limit order price. The aggregated groups for this illustrative example, sorted by adjusted limit prices (but without including the initial one-value-unit investments), are as displayed in the following table:
Table 6.8.4 AQ~re~ated, Sorted. Converted, and Adiusted Limit Orders 0 calls 0 calls 0 calls Limit QuantitLimit Quanti Limit Quanti Price" "Price" "Price 0.8495 5000 0.5495 10000 0.1395 10000 0.8395 20000 0.4995 20000 0.0995 30000 0.8345 10000 0.4695 10000 0.8195 10000 0.4295 10000 80 puts 0 puts 0 puts 0.9195 10000 0.5795 10000 0.1895 5000 0.8995 10000 0.5595 10000 0.1695 10000 0.8895 10000 0.5395 10000 0.1595 10000 0.8795 20000 0.5195 10000 0.4995 10000 After adding the initial liquidity of one value unit in each state, the initial option prices are as follows:
Table 6.8.5 MSFT Digital Options Initial Prices CALLS PUT

TRIKE IND IND BID IND OFFER IND IND BID IND OFFER
MID MID

3 0.85710.856 0.8576 0.1428 0.1423 0.1433 5 0.57140.5709 0.5719 0.4285 0.4280 0.4290 8 0.14280.1423 0.1433 0.8571 0.8566 . 0.8576 (v) According to step 6.8(S) and based upon the description of limit order processing in connection with FIG. 12, in this illustrative example an order from Table 6.8.4 is identified which has a limit "price" better or higher than the current market "price" for a given contingent claim. For example, from Table 6.9.4, there is an order for 10000 digital puts struck at 80 with limit "price" equal to .9195. The current mid-market "price" for such puts is equal to .85714.
S (vi) According to step 6.8(6), by the methods described in connection with FIG. 17, the maximum number of lots of the order for the 80 digital puts is added to already-invested amounts without increasing the recalculated mid=
market "price," with the added lots, above the limit order price of .9195.
This process discovers that, when five lots of the 80 digital put order for 10000 lots and limit "price" of .9195 are added, the new mid-market price is equal to .916667. Assuming the distribution of investments for this illustrative example, addition of any more lots will drive the mid-market price above the limit price. With the addition of these lots, the new market prices are:
- i 84 -Table 6.8.5 MSFT Digital Options Prices after addition of five lots of 80 puts CALL PUT

TRIKE IND IND BID IND OFFER IND IND BID IND OFFER
MID MID

3 0.84720.8467 0.8477 0.1527 0.1522 0.1532 0.54160.5411 0.5421 0.4583 0.4578 0.4588 8 0.08330.0828 0.0838 0.9166 0.9161 ' 0.9171 5 As can be seen from Table 6.8.5, the "prices" of the call options have decreased while the "prices" of the put options have increased as a result of filling five lots of the 80 digital put options, as expected.
(vii) According to step 6.8(7), the next step is to determine, as described in FIG.
17, whether there are any limit orders which have previously been filled whose limit "prices" are now less than the current mid-market "prices," and as such, should be subtracted. Since there are no orders than have been filled other than the just filled 80 digital put, there is no removal or "prune" step required at this stage in the process.
(viii) According to step 6.8(8), the next step is to identify another order which has a limit "price" higher than the current mid-market "prices" as a candidate for lot addition. Such a candidate is the order for 10000 lots of the 50 digital puts with limit price equal to .5795. Again the method of binary search is used to determine the maximum number of lots that can be added from this order to already-invested amounts without letting the recalculated mid-market "price" exceed the order's limit price of .5795. Using this method, it can be determined that only one lot can be added without forcing the new market "price" including the additional lot above .5795. The new prices with this additional lot are then:
-~85-Table 6.8.6 MSFT Digital Options "Prices" after (i) addition of five lots of 80 puts and S (ii) addition of one lot of SO~uts CALLS PUT

TRIKE IND IND BID IND OFFER IND IND BID IND OFFER
MID MID

3 0.82420.8237 0.8247 0.1758 0.1753 0.1763 0.47250.4720 0.4730 0.527410.52691 0.52791 80~ 0.076920.07642 0.07742 ( 0.9230770.92258 0.9235 Continuing with step 6.8(8), the next step is to identify an order whose limit "price" is now worse (i.e., lower than ) the mid-market "prices" from the most recent equilibrium calculation as shown in Table 6.8.6. As can be seen from the table, the mid-market "price" of the 80 digital put options is now 923077. The best limit order (highest "priced") is the order for 10000 lots at .9195, of which five are currently filled. Thus, the binary search routine determines the minimum number of lots which are to be removed from this order so that the order's limit "price" is no longer worse (i.e., lower than) the newly recalculated market "price." This is the removal or prune part of the equilibrium calculation.
The "add and prune" steps are repeated iteratively with intermediate multistate equilibrium allocations performed. The contract is at equilibrium when no further lots may be added for orders with limit order "prices" better than the market or removed for limit orders with "prices" worse than the market. At this point, the group of DBAR contingent claims (sometimes referred to as the "contract") is in equilibrium, which means that all of the remaining conditional investments or limit orders -- i.e., those that did not get removed -- receive "prices" in equilibrium which are equal to or better than the limit "price" conditions specified in each order. In the present illustration, the final equilibrium "prices" are:
- i 86 -Table 6.8.7 MSFT Digital Options Eguilibrium Prices CALL PUT

TRIKE IND IND BID IND OFFER IND IND BID IND OFFER
MID MID

3 0.830500.83000 0.83100 0.169490.16899 0.16999 0.480500.48000 0.4810 0.519490.51899 0.51999 8 0.139490.13899 0.13999 0.860500.86000 0.86100 Thus, at these equilibrium "prices," the following table shows which of the original orders are executed or "filled":
Table 6.8.8 ' Filled Buy Orders 0 calls 0. calls 0 calls Limit QuantitFilledLimit QuantityFilledLimit QuantityFilled "Price" "Price" "Price"

0.82 10000 0 0.43 10000 0 0.1 10000 0 0.835 10000 10000 0.47 10000 0 0.14 10000 8104 0.84 10000 10000 0.5 10000 10000 80 putsFilled 0 puts Filled 0 puts Filled ' 0.88 10000 10000 0:5 10000 0 0.16 10000 0 0.9. 10000 10000 0.52 10000 2425 0.17. 10000 2148 0.92 I 10000 ~ 10000I 0.54 10000 10000 , - ll 87 -Table 6.8.9 Filled Sell Orders 0 calls 0 calls 0 calls Limit Quanti FilledLimit Quanti FilledLimit Quanti Filled "Price" "Price "Pace"

0.81 5000 5000 0.42 10000 10000 0.11 10000 10000 0.44 10000 10000 0.12 10000 10000 80 putsFilled 0 puts Filled 0 puts Filled 0.9 20000 0 0.45 10000 10000 0.15 5000 5000 0.50 10000 10000 0.16 10000 10000 It may be possible only partially to execute or "fill" a trader's order at a given limit "price" or implied probability of the relevant states. For example, in the current illustration, the limit buy order for 50 puts at limit "price" equal to .52 for an order amount of 10000 may be only filled in the amount 2424 (see Table 6.8.8). If orders are made by more than one investor and not all of them can be filled or executed at a given equilibrium, in preferred embodiments it is necessary to decide how many of which investor's orders can be filled, and how many of which ir<vestor's orders will remain unfulfilled at that equilibrium. This may be accomplished in several ways, including by filling orders on a first-come-first-filled basis, or on a pro rata or other basis known or apparent to one of skill in the art. In preferred embodiments, investors are notified prior to the commencement of a trading period about the basis on which orders are filled when all investors' limit orders cannot be filled at a particular equilibrium.
1 S 6.9 Sensitivity Analysis and Depth of Limit Order Book In preferred embodiments of the present invention, traders in DBAR digital options may be provided with information regarding the quantity of a trade that could be executed ("filled") at a given limit "price" or implied probability for a given option, spread or strip. For example, consider the MSFT digital call option with strike of SO illustrated in Table 6.1.1 above. Assume the current "price" or implied probability of the call option is .4408 on the "offer" side of the market. A trader may desire, for example, to know what quantity of value units could be transacted and executed at any given moment for a limit "price" which is better than the market.
In a more specific example, for a purchase of the 50 strike call option, a trader may want to know how much would be filled at that moment were the trader to specify a limit "price" or implied probably of, for example, .46. This information is not necessarily readily apparent, since the acceptance of conditional investments (i.e., the execution of limit orders) changes the implied probability or "price" of each of the states in the group. As the limit "price" is increased, the quantities specified in a buy order are more likely to be filled, and a curve can be drawn with the associated limit "price"/quantity pairs. The curve represents the amount that could be filled (for example, along the X-axis) versus the corresponding limit "price" or implied probability of the strike of the order (for example, along the Y-axis). Such a curve should be useful to traders, since it provides an. indication of the "depth" of the DBAR DOE for a given contract or group of contingent claims. In other words, the curve provides information on the "price" or implied probability, for example, that a buyer would be required to accept in order to execute a predetermined or specified number of value units of investment for the digital option.
6.10 Networking of DBAR Di 't~Options Exchang-es In preferred embodiments, one or more operators of two or mare different DBAR
Digital Options Exchanges may synchronize the time at which trading periods are conducted (e.g., agreeing on the same commencement and predetermined termination criteria) and the strike prices offered for a given underlying event to be observed at an agreed upon time. Each operator could therefore be positioned to offer the same trading period on the same underlying DBAR
event of economic significance or financial instrument. Such synchronization would allow for the aggregation of liquidity of two or more different exchanges by means of computing DBAR
DOE equilibria for the combined set of orders on the participating exchanges.
This aggregation of liquidity is designed to result iri more efficient "pricing" so that implied probabilities of the various states reflect greater information about investor expectations than if a single exchange were used.
7. DBAR DOE: ANOTHER EMBODIMENT
In another embodiment of a DBAR Digital Options Exchange ("DBAR DOE"), a type of demand-based market or auction, all orders for digital options are expressed in terms of the payout (or "notional payout") received should any state of the set of constituent states of a DBAR
digital option occur (as opposed to, for example, expressing buy digital option orders in terms of premium to be invested and expressing "sell" digital option orders in terms of notional payout, or notional payout less the premium received). In this embodiment, the DBAR DOE
can accept and process limit orders for digital options expressed in terms of each trader's desired payout. In this embodiment, both buy and sell orders may be handled consistently, and the speed of calculation - ll~~ -of the equilibrium calculation is increased. This embodiment of the DBAR DOE
can be used with or without limit orders (also referred to as conditional investments).
Additionally this embodiment of the DBAR DOE can be used to trade in a demand-based market or auction based on any event, regardless of whether the event is economically significant or not.
S In this embodiment, an equilibrium algorithm (set forth in Equations 7.3.7 and 7.4.7) may be used on orders without limits (without limits on the price), to determine the prices and total premium invested into a DBAR DOE market or auction based only upon information concerning the requested payouts per order and the defined states (or spreads) for which the desired digital option is in-the-money (the payout profile for the order). The requested payout per order is the executed notional payout per order, and the trader or user pays the price determined at the end of the .trading period by the equilibrium algorithm necessary to receive the requested payout.
In this embodiment, an optimization system (also referred to as the Order Price Function or OPF) may also be utilized that maximizes the payouts per order within the constraints of the limit order. In other words, when a user or trader specifies a limit order price, and also specifies the requested payouts per order and the defined states (or spreads) for which the desired digital option is in-the-money, then the optimization system or OPF determines a price of each order that is less than or equal to each order's limit price, while maximizing the executed notional payout for the orders: As set forth below, in this limit order example, the user may not receive the requested payout but will receive a maximum executed notional payout given the limit price that the user desires to invest for the payout.
In other words, in this embodiment, three mathematical principles underlie demand-based markets or auctions: demand-based pricing and self funding conditions; how orders in digital options are constituted in a demand-based market or auction; and, how a demand-based auction or market may be implemented with standard limit orders. Similar equilibrium algorithms, optimization systems, and mathematical principles also underlie and apply to demand-based markets or auctions that include one or more customer orders for derivatives strategies or other contingent claims, that are replicated or approximated with a set of replicating claims, which can be digital options and/or vanilla options, as described in greater detail in Sections 10, 11 and 13 below. These customer orders are priced based upon a demand-based valuation of the replicating digital options and/or vanilla options that replicate the derivatives strategies, and the demand-based valuation includes the application of the equilibrium algorithm, optimization system and mathematical principals to such an embodiment.

In this DBAR DOE embodiment, for each demand-based market or auction, the demand-based pricing condition applies to every pair of fundamental contingent claims. In demand-based systems, the ratio of prices of each pair of fimdamental contingent claims is equal to the ratio of volume filled for those claims. This is a notable feature of DBAR contingent claims markets because the demand-based pricing condition relates the amount of relative volumes that may clear in equilibrium to the relative equilibrium market prices. Thus, a demand-based market microstructure, which is the foundation of demand-based market or auction, is unique among .- market mechanisms in that the relative prices of claims are directly related to the relative volume transacted of those claims. By contrast, in conventional markets, which have heretofore not - adopted demand-based principles, relative contingent claim prices typically reflect, in theory, the absence of arbitrage opportunities between such claims, but nothing is implied or can be inferred about the relative volumes demanded.of such claims in equilibrium.
Equation 7.4.7, as set forth below, is the equilibrium equation for demand-based trading in accordance with one embodiment of the present invention. It states that a demand-based trading equilibrium can be mathematically expressed in terms of a matrix eigensystem, in which the total premium collected in a demand-based market or auction (T) is equal to the maximum eigenvalue of a matrix (H) which is a function of the aggregate notional amounts executed for each fundamental spread and the opening orders. In addition, the eigenvector corresponding to this maximum eigenvalue, when normalized, contains the prices of the fundamental single strike spreads. Equation 7.4.7 shows that given aggregate notional amounts to be executed (~ and arbitrary amounts of opening orders (K), that a unique demand-based trading equilibrium results.
The equilibrium is unique because a unique total premium investment, T, is associated with a unique vector of equilibrium prices, p, by the solution of the eigensystem of Equation 7.4.7.
Demand-based markets or auctions may be implemented with a standard limit order book in which traders attach price conditions for execution of buy and sell orders.
As in any other market, limit orders allow traders to control the price at which their orders are executed,.at the risk that the orders may not be executed in full or in part. Limit orders may be an important execution control feature in demand-based auctions or markets because final execution is delayed until the end of the trading or auction period.
Demand-based markets or auctions may incorporate standard limit orders and limit order book principles. In fact, the limit order book employed in a demand-based market or auction and the mathematical expressions used therein may be compatible with standard limit order book mechanisms for other existing markets and auctions. The mathematical expression of a General Limit Order Book is an optimization problem in which the market clearing solution to the problem maximizes the volume of executed orders subject to two constraints for each order in the book. According to the first constraint, should an order be executed, the order's limit price is greater than or equal to the market price including the executed order.
According to the second constraint, the order's executed notional amount is not to exceed the notional amount requested by the trader to be executed.
7.1 Special Notation 'For the purposes of the discussion of the embodiment described in the present section, the 10.' following notation is utilized. The notation uses. some symbols :previously employed in other sections of this specification. It should be understood that the meanings of these notadonal symbols are valid as defined below onlyin the. context of the discussion in the present section (Section 7 DBAR DOE: ANOTHER EMBODIMENT as well as the discussion in relation to FIG. 19 and FIG.'20 in Section 9).
Known Variables .
m: number of defined states or spreads, a natural number. Index letter i, i=1, 2,..., m.
k: m x 1 vector where k; is the initial invested premium for state i, i=1, 2, ..., m.
k; is a natural number so k; > 0 i=1, 2, .:., m e: a vector of.ones of length m (m x 1 unit vector) n: number of orders in the market or auction, a natural number. Index letter j, j=1,2,..., n r: n x 1 vector where r~ is equal to the requested payout for order j, j= l, 2, ..., n. r~ is a natural number so r~ is positive for all j, j= 1, 2, ..., n w: n x 1 vector where w~ equals the inputted limit price for order j, j= 1, 2, ... , n Range: 0 < w~ <_ 1 for j= l, 2, ..., n for digital options 0 < w~ for j= 1, 2, ..., n for arbitrary payout options - ~ 92 -w~a: n x 1 vector where w~a is the adjusted limit price for order j after converting "sell" orders into buy orders (as discussed below) and after adjusting the inputted limit order w~ with fee f (assuming flat fee) for order j, j = 1, 2 ..., n For a "sell" order j, the adjusted limit price w~a equals (1- w~ - f) For a buy order j, the adjusted limit price w~a equals (w~ - f ) B: n x m matrix where B~,; is a positive number if the jth order requests a payout for the i~' state, and 0 otherwise. For digital options, the positive number is one.
Each row. j of B comprises a payout profile for order j.
f : transaction fee for order j, scalar (in basis points) added to and subtracted from equilibrium price to obtain offer and bid prices, respectively, and subtracted from and . added to limit prices, w~, to obtain adjusted limit price, w~a for buy and sell limit prices, respectively.
Unknown Variables x: n x 1 vector where x~ is the notional payout executed for order j in equilibrium Range: 0 < x~ < r~ for j=1, 2, ...; n y: m x 1 vector where y; is the notional payout executed per defined state i, i =1, 2, ...,m Definition:. y = BTx T: positive scalar, not necessarily an integer.
T is the total invested premium (in value units) in the contract m m n m T=~y,p,+~k;=~x~~c~+~k, r=t .=t f=t i=t T;: positive scalar, not necessarily an integer T; is the total invested premium (in value units) in state i p: m x 1 vector where p; is the price/probabiliiy for state n, i =1, 2, ..., m p; --__ k' for i=1, 2, ..., m T-y;
equilibrium price for order j ~(x): B*p, an n x 1 vector containing the equilibrium prices for each order j.
g: n x 1 vector whose j element is g~ for j= 1, 2, ..., n Definition: g ---_ B*p -w Note B*p is the vector of market prices for order j denoted by g is the difference between the market prices and the limit prices 7.2 Elements of Example DBAR DOE Embodiment In this embodiment (Section 7), traders submit orders during the DBAR market or auction that include the following data: (1) an order payout size (denoted r~), (2) a limit order price (denoted w~), and (3) the defined states for which the desired digital 'option is in-the-money (denoted as the rows of the matrix B, as described in the previous sub-section). In this embodiment, all of the order requests are in the form of payouts to be received should the defined states over which the respective options are in-the-money occur. In Section 6, an embodiment was described in which the order amounts are invested premium amounts, rather than the aforementioned payouts.
7.3 Mathematical Principles , In this embodiment of a DBAR DOE market or auction, traders are able to buy and sell digital options and spreads. The fundamental contingent claims of this market or auction are the smallest digital option spreads, i.e., those that span a single strike price.
For example, a demand-based market or auction, such as, for example, a DBAR auction or market, that offers digital call and put options with strike prices of 30, 40, 50, 60, and 70 contains six fimdamental states: the spread below and including 30; the spread between 30 and 40 including 40; the spread between and SO including 50; etc. As indicated in the previous section, in this embodiment, p; is the price of a single strike spread i and m is the number of fundamental single state spreads or "defined states." For these single strike spreads, the following assumptions are made:
- 1 ~4 -DBAR DOE Assumptions for this Embodiment m (1)~p; =1 (2)p; > 0 for i =1,..,m 7.3.1 (3)k; > 0 for i =1,..., m The first assumption, equation 7.3.1(1), is that the fundamental spread prices sum to unity. This equation holds for this embodiment as well as for other embodiments of the present invention. Technically, the sum of the fimdamental spread prices should sum to the discount factor that reflects the time value of money (i.e., the interest rate) prevailing from the time at which investors must pay for their digital options to the time at which investors receive a payout from an in-the-money option after the occurrence of a defined state. For the purposes of this description of this embodiment, the time value of money during this period will be taken to be zero, i.e., it.will be ignored so that the fimdamental spread prices sum to unity. The second assumption, equation 7.3.1(2), is that each price must be positive. Assumption 3, equation 7.3.1 (3), is that the DBAR DOE contract of the present embodiment is.
initialized (see Section 6.7, above) with value units invested in each state in the amount of k;
(initial amount of value units invested for state i).
Using the notation from Section 7.1, the Demand Reallocation Function (DRF) of this embodiment of an OPF is a canonical DRF (CDRF), setting the total amount of investments that are allocated using multistate allocation techniques to the defined states equal to the total amount of investment in the auction or market that is available (net of any transaction fees) to allocate to the payouts upon determining the defined state which has occurred.
Alternatively, a non-canonical DRF may be used in an OPF.
Under a CDRF, the total amount invested in each defined state is a function of the price in that state, the total amount of notional payout requested for that state, and the initial amount of value units invested in the defined state, or:
T = p; * y; + k; 7.3.2 The ratio of the invested amounts in any two states is therefore equal to:

Tr __ Pr * Yr + kr Ti Pi * yi + ki 7.3.3 As described previously, since each state price is equal to the total investment in the state divided by he total investment over all of the states (p; = T;/T and p~ = Tj/T), the ratio of the investment amounts in each DBAR contingent claim defined state is equal to the ratio of the prices or implied probabilities for the states, which, using the notation of Section 7.1, yields:
_T __ pr * Yr ~' kr __ _Pi Ti pi * Yi + ki pi 7.3.4 Eliminating the denominators of the previous equation and summing over j yields:
~Pi(Pc*Yr +kr)=~pr *(Pi *Yi +ki) 7.3.5 i=t i=i Substitution for T into the above equation yields:
m (Pr * Yr + kr ) ~ P; = PrT' 7.3.6 By the assumption that the state prices or probabilities sum.to unity from Equation 7.3.1, this yields the following equation:
k;
Pr = T 7.3.7 - Yr This equation yields the state price or probability of a defined state in terms of (1) the amount of value units invested in each state to initialize the DBAR auction or market (k;); (2) the total amount of premium invested in the DBAR auction or market (T); and (3) the total amount of payouts to be executed for all of the traders' orders for state i (y;). Thus, in this embodiment, Equation 7.3.7 follows from the assumptions stated above, as indicated in the equations in 7.3.1, and the requirement the DRF imposes that the ratio of the state prices for any two defined states in a DBAR auction or market be equal to the ratio of the amount of invested value units in the defined states, as indicated in Equation 7.3.4.
7.4 Equilibrium AlQ~rithm - b ~6 -From equation 7.3.7 and the assumption that the probabilities of the defined states sum to one (again ignoring any interest rate considerations), the following m+1 equations may be solved to obtain the unique set of defined state probabilities (p's) and the total premium investment for the group of defined states or contingent claims:
p; = k' , i =1,2,.., m (a) T
m y' 7.4.1 k' =1 ~Pr =~T _yi Equation 7.4.1 contains m+1 unknowns and m+1 equations. The unknowns are the p;, i=1,2,..,m, and T, the total investment for all of the defined states. In accordance with the embodiment, the method of solution of the m+1 equations is to first solve Equation 7.4.1 (b).
This equation is a polynomial in T. By the assumption that all of the probabilities of the defined states must be positive, as stated in Equation 7.3.1, and that the probabilities also sum to one, as also stated in Equation 7.3.1, the defined state probabilities are between 0 and 1 or:
0 < pt < 1, which implies 0 < T k' < 1, for i =1,2,..m, which implies - y1 7.4.2 T > yt +k1, for i =1,2,..m, which implies T > max(yl + k~ ), for i =1,2,..m So the lower bound for T is equal to:
Tio,~, = max(yi + k; ) By Equation 7.3.2:
m m m T=~T,. =~k; +~p;y; 7.4.3 t=1 t=~ i=1 Letting y~m~ be the maximum value of the y's, m m- m m m m m T = ~,ki +~,p~Y~ ~ ~,ki +~,Piy(m) -~,ki +y(m)~pi = ~ki +y(m) 7.4.4 ''~ '_' i=1 i=1 i=1 i=1 i=1 Thus, the upper bound for ~' is equal to:
_ a 97 _ m m TuPPer = ~, ki + Y(m) = m~(3'i ) '~' ~ ki 7.4. S
i=1 i=1 The solution for the total investment in the defined states therefore lies in the following interval TI~, < T <_ T"pP~, , or 7.4.6 max(y~ + k; ) < T <_ max(y; ) + ~ k; .
c=~
In this embodiment, T is determined uniquely from the equilibrium execution order amounts, denoted by the vector x. Recall that in this embodiment, y _--- BTx.
As shown above, I O T E ( Tower, Tupper~
Let the function f be .f(T)=~ k' -1=0=~p~-1 T_Y;
Further, 15 f(Tlower) ~ 0 f(T"pp~) < 0 Now,.over the range T E ( T~ow~., T"pp~), f(T) is differentiable and strictly monotonically 20 decreasing. Thus, there is a unique T in the range such that f(T) = 0 Thus, T is uniquely determined by the x~'s (the equilibrium executed notional payout amounts for each order j).
25 The solution for Equation 7.4.1 (b) can therefore be obtained using standard root-finding techniques, such as the Newton-Raphson technique, over the interval for T
stated in Equation 7.4.6. Recall that the function f(T) is defined as - R~~ -ki f(T)=~ -1 i=~ T - Y;
The first derivative of this function is therefore:
df _ -~ k;
.~ (T)- dT ,_, (T-Y~)z Thus for T, take for an initial guess ' T~ - M~(Y~+kn Y2+ kz, ...., yr,+ km) For the p+lst guess use Tp+i= TP - f(Tp) .f~(Tn) and calculate iteratively until a desired level of convergence to the root of f(T), is obtained.
Once the solution for Equation 7.4.1 (b) is obtained, the value of T can be substituted into each of the m equations in 7.4.1 (a) to solve for the p;. When the T and the p; are known, all prices for DBAR digital options and spreads may be readily calculated, as indicated by the notation in 7.1.
Note that, in the alternative embodiment with no limit orders (briefly discussed at the beginning of this section 7), there are no constraints set by limit prices, and the above equilibrium algorithm is easily calculated because x~, the executed notional payout amounts for each order j, is equal to r~ (a known quantity), the requested notional payout for order j.
Regardless of the presence of limit orders, an equivalent set of mathematics for this embodiment of a DBAR DOE is developed using matrix notation. The matrix equivalent of Equation 7.3.2 may be written as follows:
H * p = T * p 7.4.7 - 19~ -where T and p are the total premium and state probability vector, respectively, as described in Section 7.1. The matrix H, which has m rows and m columns where m is the number of defined states in the DBAR market or auction, is defined as follows:
Y1 "~' k1 k1 k~ . .. k1 k2 Y2 + k2 k2 . . . k2 H = . . . ... . 7.4.8 km km km . .. Ym .~ km H.is a matrix with m rows and m columns. Each diagonal entry of H is equal to y; + k; (the sum of the notional payout requested by all the traders for state r and the initial amount of value units invested for state r). The other entries for each row are equal to k; (the initial amount of value units invested for state r). Equation 7.4.7 is an eigenvalue problem, where:
H=Y+K*V
Y = an m x m diagonal matrix of the aggregate notional amounts to be executed, Y;,; = y;
K = an m x m diagonal matrix of the arbitrary amounts of opening orders, K;,;
= k;
V = an m x m matrix of ones, V,-~ = 1 T = max (7v,;(H)), i.e., the maximum eigenvalue of the matrix H; and p = w(H,T)~, i.e., the normalized eigenvector associated with the eigenvalue T.
Thus, Equation 7.4.7 is, in this embodiment, a method of mathematically describing the equilibrium of a DBAR digital options market or auction that is unique given the aggregate notional amounts to be executed (Y) and arbitrary amounts of opening orders (K). The equilibrium is unique since a unique total premium investment, T, is associated with a unique vector of equilibrium prices, p, by the solution of the eigensystem of Equation 7.4.7.
7.5 Sell Orders In this embodiment, "sell" orders in a DBAR digital options market or auction are processed as complementary buy orders with limit prices equal to one minus the limit price of the "sell" order. For example, for the MSFT Digital Options auction of Section 6, a sell order for the 50 calls with a limit price of .44 would be processed as a complementary buy order for the SO
-2Q~-puts (which are complementary to the 50 calls in the sense that the defined states which are spanned by the 50 puts are those which are not spanned by the 50 calls) with limit price equal to .56 (i.e., 1-.44). In this manner, buy and sell orders, in this embodiment of this Section 7, may both be entered in terms of notional payouts. Selling a DBAR digital call, put or spread for a S given limit price of an order j ( w~) is equivalent to buying the complementary digital call, put, or spread at the complementary limit price of order j (1- w~).
7.6 Arbitrary Payout Options In this embodiment, a trader may desire an option that has a payout should the option expire in the money that varies depending upon which defined in-the-money state occurs. For example, a trader may desire twice the payout if the state [40,50) occurs than if the state [30;40) occurs. Similarly; a trader may desire that an option have a payout that is linearly increasing over the defined range of in-the-money states ("strips" as defined in Section 6 above) in order to ' approximate the types of options available in non-DBAR, traditional markets.
Options with arbitrary payout profiles can readily be accommodated with the DBAR methods of the pr-esent invention. In particular, the B matrix, as described in Section 7.2 above, can readily represent such options in this embodiment. For example, consider a DBAR contract with S
defined states.
If a trader desires an option that has the payout profile (0,0,1,2,3), i.e., an option that is in-the-rnoney only if the last 3 states occur, and for which the fourth state has a payout twice the third, and the fifth state a payout three times the third, then the row of the B
matrix corresponding to this order is equal to (0,0,1,2,3). By contrast, a digital option for which the same three states are in-the-money would have a corresponding entry in the B matrix of (0,0,1,1,1 ).
Additionally, for digital options all prices, both equilibrium market prices and limit prices, are bound between 0 arid 1. This is because all options are equally weighted linear combinations of the defined state probabilities. If, however, options with arbitrary payout distributions are processed, then the linear combinations (as based upon the rows of the B matrix) will not be weighted equally and prices need not be bounded between 0 and 1. For ease of exposition, the bulk of the disclosure in this Section 7 has assumed that digital options (i.e., equally weighted payouts) are the only options under consideration.
7.7 Limit Order Book Optimization In this embodiment of a DBAR digital options exchange or market or auction as described in this Section 7, traders may enter orders for digital calls, puts, and spreads by placing conditional investment or limit orders. As indicated previously in Section 6.8, a limit order is an - 20t -order to buy or sell a digital call, put or spread that contains a price (the "limit price") worse than which the trader desires not to have his order executed. For example, for a buy order of a digital call, put, or spread, a limit order will contain a limit price which indicates that execution should occur only if the final equilibrium price of the digital call, put or spread is at or below the limit price for the order. Likewise, a limit sell order for a digital option will contain a limit price which indicates that the order is to be executed if the final equilibrium price is at or higher than the limit sell price. All orders are processed as buy orders and are subject to execution whenever the order's limit price is greater than or equal to the then prevailing equilibrium price, because sell orders may be represented as buy orders, as described in the previous section.
In this embodiment, accepting limit orders for a DBAR digital options exchange uses the solution of a nonlinear optimization problem (one example of an OPF). The problem seeks to maxiriiize the sum total of notional payouts of orders that can be executed in equilibrium subject to each order's limit price and the DBAR digital options equilibrium'Equation 7.4.7.
Mathematically; the nonlinear optimization that represents the DBAR digital options market or . ' auction limit order book may be expressed as follows:
n x* = argmax ~x j subject to (1) gj(x)=xj(~cj(x)w'vj)~0 7.7.1 (2) 0<_xj <_rj (3) Hp = Tp The objective function of the optimization problem in 7.7.1 is the sum of the payout amounts for all of the limit orders that may be executed in equilibrium. The first constraint, 7.7.1(1), requires that the limit price be greater than or equal to the equilibrium price for any payout to be executed in equilibrium (recalling that all orders, including "sell" orders, may be processed as buy orders).
The second constraint, 7.7.1 (2), requires that the execution payout for the order be positive and less than or equal to the requested payout of the order. The third constraint, 7.7.1(3) is the DBAR digital option equilibrium equation as described in Equation 7.4.7. These constraints also apply to DBAR or demand-based markets or auctions, in which contingent claims, such as derivatives strategies, are replicated with replicating claims (e.g., digital options and/or vanilla options), and then evaluated based on a demand-based. valuation of these replicating claims, as described in Sections 10, 11 and 13 below.
7.8 Transaction Fees In this embodiment, before solving the nonlinear optimization problem, the limit order prices for "sell" orders provided by the trader are converted into buy orders (as discussed above) and both buy and "sell" limit order prices are adjusted with the exchange fee or transaction fee, f .
The transaction fee can be set for zero, or it can be expressed as a flat fee as set forth in this embodiment which is added to the limit order price received for "sell" orders, and subtracted from the limit order price paid for buy orders to arrive at an adjusted limit order price w~a for .10 ~ order j; as follows:
For a "sell" order j, w~a= 1 - w~ - f 7.8.1 For a buy order j, w~a = w~ - f 7.8.2 Alternatively, if the transaction fee f is variable, and expressed as a percentage of the limit order price, w~, then the limit order price may be adjusted as follows:
For a "sell" order j, v~'~a- (1- v~'i)*(1- f) 7.8.3 For a buy order j, w~a =w~*(1- f) 7.8.4 The transaction fee f can also depend on the time of trade, to provide incentives for traders to trade early or to trade certain strikes, or otherwise reflect liquidity conditions in the contract. .Regardless of the type of transaction fee f, the limit order prices w~ should be adjusted to w~a before beginning solution of the nonlinear optimization program.
Adjusting the limit order . price adjusts the location of the outer boundary for optimization set by the limiting equation 7.7.1(1). After the optimization solution has been reached, the equilibrium prices for each executed order j, ~(x) can be adjusted by adding the transaction fee to the equilibrium price to produce the market offer price, and by subtracting the transaction fee from the equilibrium price to produce the market bid price. The limit and equilibrium prices for each executed customer order, in an example embodiment in which derivative strategies are replicated into a digital or vanilla replicating basis, and then subject to a demand-based valuation, as more fully set forth in Sections 10, 11 and 13, can similarly be adjusted with transaction fees.

7.9 An Embodiment of the AlQOrithm to Solve the Limit Order Book Optimization In this embodiment, the solution of Equation 7.7.1 can be achieved with a stepping iterative algorithm, as described in the following steps:
(1) Place Opening Orders: For each state, premium equal to k;, for i =
1,2,...,m, is invested. These investments are called the "opening orders." The size of such investments, in this embodiment, are generally small relative to the subsequent orders.
(2) Convert all "sale" orders to complementary buy orders. As indicated previously in Section 6.8, this is achieved by (i) identifying the range of defined states i complementary to the states being "sold"; and (ii) adjusting the limit "price"
(w~) to one minus the original limit "price" (1- w~). Note that by contrast to the method disclosed in Section 6.8, there is no need to convert the amount being sold into an equivalent amount being bought. . In this embodiment in this section, both buy and "sell" orders are expressed in terms of payout (or notional payout) terms.
(3) For all limit orders, adjust the limit "prices" ( w~, 1- w~) with transaction fee, by subtracting the transaction fee f : For a "sell" order j, the adjusted limit price w~a therefore equals (1 - w~ + f ), while for a buy order j, the adjusted limit price w~a equals (w~ - f ).
(4) As indicated above in Section 6.8, group the limit orders by placing all of the limit orders that span or comprise the same range of defined states into the same group.
Sort each group from the best (highest "price" buy) to the worst (lowest "price"
buy).
(S) Establish an initial iteration step size, a~(1). In this embodiment the initial iteration step size a~(1) may be chosen to bear some reasonable relationship to the . expected order sizes to be encountered in the DBAR digital options market or auction. In most applications, an initial iteration step size a~( 1 ) equal to 100 is adequate. The current step size a~(x) will initially equal the initial iteration step size (a~(x) = a~(1) for first iteration) until and unless the current step size is adjusted to a different step size.
(6) Calculate the equilibrium to obtain the total investment amount T and the state probabilities, p, using equation 7.4.7. Although the eigenvalues can be computed -2~4-directly, this embodiment finds T by.Newton-Raphson solution of Equation 7.4.1 (b). The solution to T and equation 7.4.1 (a) is used to find the p's.
(7) Compute the equilibrium order prices ~c(x) using the p's obtained in step (5). The equilibrium order prices ~(x) are equal to B*p.
(8) Increment the orders (x~) that have adjusted limit prices (w~a) greater than or equal to the current equilibrium price for that order ~(x) (obtained in step (6)) by the current step size a~(K), but not to exceed the requested notional payout of the order, r~. Decrement the orders (x~) that have a positive executed order amount (x~
> 0) and have limit prices less than the current equilibrium market price ~(x) by the current step size a~(K), but not to an amount less than zero.
(9) Repeat steps (5) to (7) in subsequent iterations until the values obtained for the executed order amounts (x~'s) achieve a desired convergence, as measured by certain convergence criteria (set forth in Step(8)a), periodically adjusting the current step size a~(x) and/or the iteration process.after the initial iteration to further progress the stepping iterative process towards the desired convergence.
The adjustments are set forth in steps (8)b to (8)d.
(8)a In this embodiment, the stepping iterative algorithm is considered converged based upon a number of convergence criteria. One such criterion is a convergence .
of the state probabilities ("prices") of the individual defined states. A
sampling window can be chosen, similar to the method by which the rate of progress statistic is measured (described below), in order to measure whether the state probabilities are fluctuating or are merely undergoing slight oscillations (say at the level of 10'5) that would indicate a tolerable level of convergence. Another convergence criterion, in this embodiment, would be to apply a similar rate of progress statistic to the order steps themselves. Specifically, the iterative stepping algorithm may be considered converged when all of the rate of progress statistics in Equation 7.9.1 (c) below are tolerably close to zero. As another convergence criterion, in this embodiment, the iterative stepping algorithm will be considered converged when, in possible combination with other convergence criteria, the amount of payouts to be paid should any given defined state occur does not exceed the total amount of investment in the defined states, T, by a tolerably small amount, such as 10-5*T.

(8)b In this embodiment, the step size may be increased and decreased dynamically based upon the experienced progress of the iterative scheme. If, for example, the iterative increments and decrements are making steady linear progress, then it may be advantageous to increase the step size. Conversely, if the iterative increments and decrements ("stepping") is making less than linear progress or, in the extreme case; is making little or no progress, then it is advantageous to reduce the size of the iterative step.
In this embodiment, the step size maybe accelerated and decelerated using the following:
afflue (a) . . rnod('~ ) = 0, x > w (b) w xj(x) xj(x' Y (x) - m (c) ~lxi (1) - x j (t -1)l 7.9.1 r,(x)~B-1 ) * a j (x 1)~ Y j (x) > 1 a~ (x) _ 8 (d) er,(K)~e-~ * a, (x -1) Y, (K) ~ 1 B
where Equation 7.9.1 (a) contains the parameters of the acceleration/deceleration rules. These parameters have the following interpretation:
0: a parameter that controls the rate of step size acceleration and deceleration.
Typically, the values for this parameter will range between 2 and 4, indicating .
that a maximum range of acceleration from 100-300%.
~.: a multiplier parameter, which, when used to multiply the parameter 8, yields a number of iterations over which the step size remains unchanged. Typically, the range of values for this parameter are 3 to 10.
-~0~-~: the window length parameter, which is the product of 8 and p over which the step size remains unchanged. The window parameter is a number of iterations over which the orders are stepped with a faced step size. After these number of iterations, the progress is assessed, and the step size for each order may be accelerated or decelerated. Based upon the above described ranges for 8 and p, the range of values for w is between 6 and 40, i.e., every 6 to 40 iterations the step size is evaluated for possible acceleration or deceleration.
x: the variable denoting the current iteration of the step algorithm where x is an integer multiple of the window length, t~.
71(x): a calculated statistic, calculated at every x~' iteration for each order j. The statistic is a ratio of two quantities. The numerator is the absolute value of the difference between the quantity of order j filled at the iteration corresponding to the beginning of the window and at the iteration at the end of window. It represents, for each order j, the total amount of progress made, in terms of the execution of order j by either incrementing or decrementing the executed quantity of order j, from the start of the window to the end of the window iteration. The denominator is the sum of the absolute changes of the order execution for each iteration of the window. Thus, if an order has made no progress, the y~(x) statistic will be zero. If each step has resulted in progress in the same direction the y~(x) statistic will equal one. Thus, in this embodiment, the y~(x) statistic represents the amount of progress that has been made over the previous iteration window, with zero corresponding to no progress for order j and one corresponding to linear progress for order j.
a~(x): this parameter is the current step size for order j at iteration count x. At every x~' iteration, it is updated using the equation 7.9.1 (d). If the y~(x) statistic reflects sufficient progress over the previous window by exceeding the quantity 1/ 8, then 7.9.1(d) provides for an increase in the step size, which is accomplished through a multiplication of the current step size by a number exceeding one as governed by the formula in 7.9.1(d). Similarly, if the ~y~(x) statistic reflects insufficient progress by being equal or less than 1/0, the step size parameter will remain the same or will be reduced according to the formula in 7.9.1 (d).
These parameters are selected, in this embodiment, based upon, in part, the overall performance of the rules with respect to test data. Typically, 0=2-4, p=3-10 and therefore w=6-40. Different parameters may be selected depending upon the overall performance of the rules. Equation 7.9.1 (b) states that the acceleration or deceleration of an iterative step for each order's executed amount is to be performed only on the w-th iteration, i.e., cu is a sampling window of a number of iterations (say 6-40) over which the iterative stepping procedure is evaluated to determine its rate of progress. Equation 7.9.1 (c) is the rate of progress statistic that is calculated over the length of each sampling window. The statistic is calculated for each order j on every c~-th iteration and measures the rate of 1 S progress over the previous c~ iterations of stepping. For each order, the numerator is the absolute value of how much each order j has been stepped over the sampling window. The larger the numerator, the larger the amount of total progress that has been made over the window. The denominator is the sum of the absolute values of the progress made over each individual step within the window, summed over the number of steps, w, in the window. The denominator will be the same value, for.example, whether 10 positive steps of 100 have been made or whether S
positive steps of 100 and 5 negative steps of 100 have been made for a given order. The ratio of the numerator and denominator of Equation 7.9.1 (c) is therefore a statistic that resides on the interval between 0 and 1, inclusive.
If; for example, an order j has not made any progress over the window period, then the numerator is zero and the statistic is zero. If, however, an order j has made maximum progress over the window period, the rate of progress statistic will be equal to 1. Equation 7.9.1 (d) describes the rule based upon the rate of progress statistic. For each order j at iteration K (where K is a multiple of the window length), if the rate of progress statistic exceeds 1/0, then the step size is accelerated. A higher choice of the parameter 8 will result in more frequent and larger accelerations. If the rate of progress statistic is less than or equal to 1/9, -20~-then the step size is either kept the same or decelerated. It may be possible to employ similar and related acceleration and deceleration rules, which may have a somewhat different mathematical parameterization as that described above, to the iterative stepping of the order amount executions.
(8)c In this embodiment, a linear program may be used, in conjunction with the iterative stepping algorithm described above, to further accelerate the rate of progress. The linear program would be employed primarily at the point when a tolerable level of convergence in the defined state probabilities has been achieved.
When the defined state probabilities have reached a tolerable level of convergence, the nonlinear program of Equation 7.7.1 is transformed, with prices held constant, into a linear program. The linear program may be solved using widely available techniques and software code. The linear program may be solved using a variety of numerical tolerances on the set of linear constraints. The linear program will yield a result that is either feasible or infeasible. The result contains the maximum sum of the executed order amounts (sum of the x~), subject to the price, bounds, and equilibrium constraints of Equation 7.7.1, but with the prices (the vector p) held constant. In frequent cases, the linear program will result in executed order amounts that are larger than those in possession at the current iteration of the stepping procedure. After the linear program is solved, the iterative stepping procedure is resumed with the executed order amounts from the linear program. The linear program is an optimization program of Equation 7.7.1 but with the vector p from the current iteration x held constant. With prices constant, constraints (1) and (3) of nonlinear optimization problem 7.7.1 become linear and therefore Equation 7.7.1 is transformed from a nonlinear optimization program to a linear program.
(8)d Once a tolerable level of convergence has been achieved for the notional payout executed for each order, x~, the entire stepping iterative algorithm to solve Equation 7.7.1 may then be repeated with a substantially smaller step size, e.g., a step size, a~(x), equal to 1 until a higher level of convergence has been achieved.
This incremental iteration process also applies to determine the equilibrium prices of the replicating claims in the auction and the equilibrium prices of the derivatives strategies, and the - 20~ -premiums of the customer orders, and resolve the set of equilibrium conditions, as more fully set forth in Sections 10, 11 and 13.
7.10 Limit Order Book Display S In this embodiment of a DBAR digital options market or auction, it may be desirable to inform market or auction participants of the amount of payout that could be executed at any given limit price for any given DBAR digital call, put, .or spread, as described previously in Section 6.9. The information may be displayed in such a manner so as to inform traders and other market participants the amount of an order that may be bought and "sold"
above and below the 'current market price, respectively, for any digital call, put, or spread option. In this embodiment, such a display of information of the limit order book appears in a manner similar to the data displayed in the following table.
Table 7.10.1 Current Pricing StrikeSpread Bid Offer Payout Volume To <50 0.2900 0.3020 3.3780 110,000,000 ~

<50 PUT

Offer Offer Side Volume 0.35 140,002,581 0.32 131,186;810 0.31 130,000,410 MARKET PRICE 0.2900 0.3020MARI~T PRICE

120,009,731 0.28 120,014,128 0.27 120,058,530 0.24 Bid Side Volume Bid In Table 7.10.1, the amount of payout that a trader could execute were he willing to place an order at varying limit prices above the market (for buy orders) and below the market (for "sell"
orders) is displayed. As displayed in the table, the data pertains to a put option, say for MSFT
stock as in Section 6, at a strike price of 50. The current price is .2900/.3020 indicating that the last "sale" order could have been processed at .2900 (the current bid price) and that the last buy order could have been processed at .3020 (the current offer price). The current amount of executed notional volume for the 50 put is equal to 110,000,000. The data indicate that a trader willing to place a buy order with limit price equal to .31 would be able to execute approximately 130,000,000 notional payout. Similarly, a trader willing to place a "sell"
order with limit price equal to .28 would be able to achieve indicative execution of approximately 120,000,000 in notional.
7.11. . Unique Price Equilibrium Proof The following is a proof that a solution to Equation 7.7.1 results in a unique price equilibrium.
The first-order optimality conditions for Equation 5 yield the following complementary conditions:
(1)g~ (x) < 0 -~ x~ = r~
. . (2)g~ (x) > 0 -~ x~ = 0 7.11.1A
(3)g~ (x) = 0 -~ 0 S x~ S ri The first condition is that if an order's limit price is higher than the market price (gl(x)<0), then that order is fully filled (i.e., filled in the amount of the order request, r~). The second condition is that an order not be filled if the order's limit price is less than the market equilibrium price (i.e., g7~(x)>0). Condition 3 allows for orders to be filled in all or part in the case where the order's limit price exactly equals the market equilibrium price.
To prove the existence and convergence to a unique price equilibrium, consider the following iterative mapping:
F(x) = x - /3 * g(x) 7.11.2A
Equation 7.11.2A can be proved to be contraction mapping which for a step size independent of x will globally converge to a unique equilibrium, i.e., it can be proven that Equation 2A has a unique fixed point of the form' F(x*) = x * 7.11.3A
-2~~ -To first show that F(x) is a contraction mapping, matrix differentiation of Equation 2A yields:
d~ )=j-~*D(x) where D(x)=B*A*Z-' *Br 7.11.4A
p~ *(1-p~)~i =j ~,i = - P~ * pi ~ i $ j _ T-Ya+Pc*Y«i=j Z~.i -pi y;,i ~ j S The matrix D(x) of Equation 4A is the matrix of order price first derivatives (i.e., the order price Jacobian). Equation 7.11.2A can be shown to be a contraction if the following condition holds:
dF(x)I < 1 7.11.5A
which is 'the case if the following condition holds:
~3 * p(D) < l, where 7.11.6A
p(D) = max(~,, (D)), i.e., the spectral radius of D
By the Gerschgorin's Circle Theorem the eigenvalues of A are bounded between 0 and 1. The matrix Z 1 is a diagonally dominant matrix, all rows of which sum to 1/T.
Because of the diagonal dominance, the other eigenvalues of Z 1 are clustered around the diagonal elements of the matrix, and are approximately equal to pilkl. The largest eigenvalue of Z
1 is therefore bounded above by 1/ki. The spectral radius ofD is therefore bounded between 0 and linear combinations of 1/k1 as follows:
P(D) ~ L
L= mll 7.11.7A
k;
where the quantity L, a function of the opening order amounts, can be interpreted as the "liquidity capacitance" of the demand-based trading equilibrium (mathematically L is quite similar to the total capacitance of capacitors in series). The function F(x) of Equation 2A
is therefore a contraction if R < L 7.11.8A
Equation 7.11.8A states that a contraction to the unique price equilibrium can be guaranteed for contraction step sizes no larger than L, which is an increasing function of the opening orders in the demand-based market or auction.
The fixed point iteration of Equation 2A converges to x*. Since y* BTx*, y*
can be used in Equation 7.4.7 to compute the fundamental state prices p* and the total quantity of premium invested T*. If there are linear dependencies in the B matrix, it may be possible to preserve p*
through a different allocation of the x's corresponding to the linearly dependent rows of B. For example, consider two orders, x1 and x2, which span the same states and have the same limit order price. Assume that r1=100 and r2=100 and that xl* x2*=50 from the fixed point iteration.
1 S Then clearly, x1=100 and x2=0 may be set without disturbing p*. For example, different order priority rules may give execution precedence to the earlier submitted identical order. In any event, the fixed point iteration results in a unique price equilibrium, that is, unique in p.
8. NETWORK IMPLEMENTATION
A-network implementation of the embodiment described in Section 7 is a means to run a complete, market-neutral, self hedging open book of limit orders for digital options. The network implementation is formed from a combination of demand-based trading core algorithms with an electronic interface and a demand-based limit order book. This embodiment enables the exchange or sponsor to create products, e.g., a series of demand-based auctions or markets specific to an underlying event, in response to customer demand by using the network implementation to conduct the digital options markets or auctions. These digital options, in turn, form the foundation for a variety of investment, risk management and speculative strategies that can be used by market participants. As shown in FIG. 22, whether accessed using secure, browser-based interfaces over web sites on the Internet or an extension of a private network, the network implementation provides market makers with all the functionality conduct a successful market or auction including, for example:
_2p3_ (1) Order entry. Orders are taken by a market maker's sales force and entered into the network implementation.
(2) Limit order book. All limit orders are displayed.
(3) Indicative pricing and volumes. While an auction or market is in progress, prices and order volumes are displayed and updated in real time.
(4) Price publication. Prices may be published using the market maker's intranet (for a private network implementation) or Internet web site (for an Internet implementation) in addition to market data services such as Reuters and Bloomberg.
(5) -Complete real-time distribution of market expectations. The network implementation provides market participants with a display of the complete distribution of expected returns at all times.
(6) Final pricing and order amounts. At the conclusion of a market or an auction, final prices and filled orders are displayed and delivered to the market maker for entry or export to existing clearing and settlement systems.
(7) Auction or Market administration. The network implementation provides all functions necessary to administer the market or auction, including start and stop functions, and details and summary of all orders by customer and salesperson.
A practical example of a demand-based market or auction conducted using the network . implementation follows. The example assumes that an investment bank receives inquiries for derivatives whose payouts are based upon a corporation's quarterly earnings release. At present, no underlying tradable supply of quarterly corporate earnings exists and few investment banks would choose to coordinate the "other side" of such a transaction in a continuous market.
Establishing the Market or Auction: First, the sponsor of the market or auction establishes and communicates the details that define the market or auction, including the following:
~ An underlying event, e.g., the scheduled release of an earnings announcement ~ An auction period or trading period, e.g., the specified date and time period for the market or auction ~ ,Digital options strike prices, e.g., the specified increments for each strike Accepting and Processing Customer Limit Orders: During the auction or trading period, customers may place buy and sell limit orders for any of the calls or puts, as defined in the market or auction details establishing the market or auction.
Indicative and Final Clearing of the Limit Order Book: During the auction or trading period, the network implementation displays indicative clearing prices and quantities, i.~., those that would -21~-exist if the order book were cleared at that moment. The network implementation also displays the limit order book~for each option, enabling market participants to assess market depth and conditions. Clearing prices and quantities are determined by the available intersection of limit orders as calculated according to embodiments of the present invention. At the end of the auction or trading period, a final clearing of the order book is performed and option prices and filled order quantities are finalized. Market participants remit and accept premium for filled orders. This completes a successful market or auction of digital options on an event with no underlying tradable supply.
Summary~ of Demand-Based Market or Auction Benefits: Demand-based markets or auctions can operate efficiently without the requirement of a discrete order match between and among buyers and sellers of derivatives. The mechanics of demand-based markets or auctions are transparent. Investment, risk management and speculative demand exists for large classes of economic events, risks and variables for which no associated tradable supply exists. Demand-based markets and auctions meet these demands.
9. STRUCTURED INSTRUMENT TRADING
In another embodiment, clients can offer instruments suitable to broad classes of investors. In particular, an opportunity exists for participation in demand-based markets or auctions by customers who would otherwise not participate because they typically avoid leverage and trading in derivatives contracts. In this embodiment, these customers may transact using existing financial instruments or other structured products, for example, risk-linked notes and swaps, simultaneously with customers transacting using DBAR contingent claims, for example, digital options, in the same demand-based market or auction.
In this embodiment, a set of one or more digital options are created to approximate one or more parameters of the structured products, e.g., a spread to LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate) or a coupon on a risk-linked note or swap, a note notional (also referred to, for example, as a face amount of the note or par or principal), and/or a trigger level for the note or swap to expire in-the-money. The set of one or more digital options may be referred to, for example, as an approximation set. The structured products become DBAR-enabled products;
because, once their parameters are approximated, the customer is enabled to trade them alongside other DBAR
contingent claims, for example, digital options.
The approximation, a type of mapping from parameters of structured products to parameters of digital options, could be an automatic function built into a computer system accepting and processing orders in the demand-based market or auction. The approximation or mapping permits or enables non-leveraged customers to interface with the demand-based market or auction, side by side with leverage-oriented customers who trade digital options. DBAR-.' enabled notes and swaps, as well as other DBAR-enabled products, provide non-leveraged S customers the ability to enhance returns and achieve investment objectives in new ways, and increase the overall liquidity and risk pricing efficiency of the demand-based market or auction by increasing the variety and number of participants in the market or auction.
9.1 Overview: Customer-Oriented DBAR-enabled Products Instruments can be offered to fit distinct investment styles, needs, and philosophies of a variety of customers. In this embodiment, "clientele effects" refers to, for example, the factors that would motivate different groups of customers to transact in one type of DBAR-enabled product.over another. The following classes of customers may have varying preferences, institutional constraints, and investment and risk management philosophies relevant to the nature and degree of participation in demand-based markets or auctions:
~ Hedge Funds ~ Proprietary Traders ~ Derivatives Dealers ~ Portfolio Managers ~ Insurers and Reinsurers ~ Pension Funds Regulatory, accounting, internal institutional policies; and other related constraints may affect the ability, willingness, and frequency of participation in leveraged investments in general and derivatives products such as options, futures, and swaps in particular.
Hedge fiends and proprietary traders, for instance, may actively trade digital options, but may be unlikely to trade in certain structured note products that have identical risks while requiring significant capital.
On the other hand, "real money" accounts such as portfolio managers, insurers, and pension funds may 'actively trade instruments that bear significant event risk, but these real money customers may be unlikely to trade DBAR digital options bearing identical event risks.
For example, according to the prospectus for their total return fiend, one particular fixed income manager may invest in fixed income securities for which the return of principal and payment of interest are contingent upon the non-occurrence of a specific 'trigger' event, such as a hurncane, earthquake, tornado, or other phenomenon (referred to, for example, as 'event-linked bonds'). These instruments typically pay a spread to LIBOR should losses not exceed a stipulated level.
On the other hand, a fixed-income manager may not trade in an Industry Loss Warranty market or auction with insurers (discussed above in Section 3), even though the risks transacted in this market or auction, effectively a market or auction for digital options on property risks posed by hurricanes, may be identical to the risks borne in the underwritten Catastrophe-linked (CAT) securities. Similarly, the fixed-income manager and other fixed income managers may participate widely in the corporate bond market, but may participate to a lesser extent in the default swap market (convertible into a demand-based market or auction), even though a corporate bond bears similar risks as a default swap bundled.with a traditional LIBOR-based note or wap.
The unifying theme to these clientele effects is that the structure and form in which products are offered can impact the degree of customer participation in demand-based markets or auctions, especially for real money customers which avoid leverage and trade few, if any, options but actively seek fixed-income-like instruments offering significant spreads to LIBOR for bearing some event-related risk on an active and informed basis.
This embodiment addresses these "clientele effects" in the risk-bearing markets by allowing demand-based markets or auctions to simultaneously offer both digital options and DBAR-enabled products, such as, for example, risk-linked FRNs (or floating rate notes) and .
swaps, to different customers within the same risk-pricing, allocation, and execution mechanism.
Thus, hedge funds, arbitrageurs, and derivatives dealers can transact in the demand-based market or auction in terms of digital options, while real money customers can transact in the demand-based market or auction in terms of different sets of instruments: swaps and notes paying spreads to LIBOR. For both types of customers, the payout is contingent upon an observed outcome of an economic event, for example, the level of the economic statistic at the release date (or e.g., at the end of the observation period).
9.2 Overview: FRNs and swans For FRN and swap customers, according to this embodiment, a nexus of counterparties to contingent LIBOR-based cash flows based upon material risky events can be created in a demand-based market or auction. Schematically, the cash flows resemble a multiple counterparty version of standard FRN or swap L1BOR-based cash flows. FIG. 23 illustrates the cash flows for each participant. The underlying properties of DBAR markets or auctions will -2~7-still apply (as described below), the offering of this event-linked FRN is market-neutral and self hedging. In this embodiment, as with other embodiments of the present invention, a demand-based market or auction is created, ensuring that the receivers of positive spreads to LIBOR are being funded, and completely offset, by those out-of the-money participants who receive par.
In this example; with actual ECI at 0.9%, the participants, each with trigger levels of 0.7%, 0.8%, or 0.9% are all in-the-money, and will earn LIBOR plus the corresponding spread for those triggers on. Those participants with trigger levels above 0.9%
receive par.
9.3 Parameters: FRNs and swaps vs. d~ital options The following information provides an illustration of parameters related to a principal-protected Employment Cost Index(ECI)-linked FRN note and swap and ECI-linked digital options:
~ End of Trading Period: October 23, 2001 ~ End of Observation Period: October 25, 2001 ~ Coupon Reset Date: October 25, 2001 (also referred to, for example, as the "FRN Fixing Date") ~ Note Maturity: January 25, 2002 (when par amount needs to be repaid) ~ Option payout date: January 25, 2002 (when payout of digital option is paid, can be set to be the same date as Note Maturity or a different date) ~ Trigger Index: Employment Cost Index ("ECI") (also known as the strike price for an equivalent DBAR digital option) ~ Principal Protection: Par Table 9.3- Indicative Trigger Levels and Indicative Pricing Spread to LIBOR*
CI Tri er s %

0.7 50 .8 0 .9 180 1.1 00 ~1.2 - .' 1200 *For the purposes of the example, assume mid-market LIBOR execution In this example, a customer (for example, an FRN holder or a note holder) places an order for an FRN with $100,000,000 par (also referred to, for example, as the face value of the note or notional or principal of the note), selecting a trigger of 0.9% ECI and a minimum spread of 180 bps to LIBOR (180 basis points or 1.80% in addition to LIBOR) during a trading period. After the end of the trading period, October 23, 2001, if the market or auction determines the coupon for the note (e.g., the spread to LIBOR) equal to 200 bps to LIBOR, and the customer's note expires in-the-money at the end of the observation period, October 25, 2001, then the customer will receive a return of 200bps plus LIBOR on par ($100,000,000) on the note maturity date, January 25, 2002.
Alternatively, if the market or auction fixes the rate on the note or sets the spread to 180 bps to LIBOR, and the customer's note expires-in-the money at the end of the observation period, then the customer will receive a return of 180 bps plus LIBOR (the selected minimum spread) on par on the note maturity date. If a 3-month LIBOR is equal to 3.5%, and the spread of 1$0 bps to LIBOR is also for a 3 month period, and the note expires in-the-money, then the customer receives a payout $101,355,444.00 on January 25, 2002, or:
daycount in - the - money payout = par + par x ( LIBOR + spread ~ x basis 9.3A
An "in-the-money note payout" may be a payout that the customer receives if the FRN
expires in-the-money. Analogously, an "out-of the-money note payout" may be a payout that the customer receives if the FRN expires out-of the-money. "Daycount" is the number of days between the end of the coupon reset date and the note maturity date (in this example, 92 days).
Basis is the number of days used to approximate a year, often set at 360 days in many financial calculations. The variable, "daycount/basis" is the fraction of a year between the observation -2ll9-period and the note maturity date, and is used to adjust the relevant annualized interest rates into effective interest rates for a fraction of a year.
If the note expires out-of the-money, because the ECI is observed to be 0.8%, for example, on October 25, 2001 (the end of the observation period), then the customer receives an out-of the-money payout of par on January 25, 2002, the note maturity date, or:
out - of - the - money note payout = par 9.3B
Alternatively, the FRN could be structured as a swap, in which case the exchange of par does.not occur. If the swap is structured to adjust.the interest rates into effective interest rates for the actual amount of time elapsed between the end of the observation period and the note maturity date, then the customer receives a swap payout of $1,355,444. If the ECI fixes below 0.9% (and the swap is structured to adjust the interest rates), then the FRN
holder loses or pays a swap loss of $894,444 or LIBOR times par (see equation 9.3D). The swap payout and swap loss can be formulated as follows:
daycount 9.3C
swap payout = par x (LIBOR + spread) x basis daycount swap loss = par x LIBOR x 9.3D
basis As opposed to FRNs and swaps, digital options provide a notional or a payout at a digital payout date, occurring on or after the end of the observation period (when the outcome of the underlying event has been observed). The digital payout date can be set at the same time as the note maturity date or can occur at some other earlier time, as described below. The digital option customer can specify a desired or requested payout, a selected outcome, and a limit on the investment amount for limit orders (as opposed to market orders, in which the customer does not place a limit on the investment amount needed to achieve the desired or requested payout).
9.4 Mechanics: DBAR-enabling FRNs and swans In this embodiment, as discussed above, both digital options and risk-linked FRNs or swaps may be offered in the same demand-based market or auction. Due to clientele effects, traditional derivatives customers may follow the market or auction in digital option format, while flee real money customers may participate in the market or auction ire an FRI~
format. Digital - 22~ -options customers may submit orders, inputting option notional (as a desired payout), a strike price (as a selected outcome), and a digital option limit price (as a limit on the investment amount). FRN customers may submit orders, inputting a notional note size or par, a minimum spread to LIBOR, and a trigger level or levels, indicating the level (equivalently, a strike price) at S or above which the FRN will earn the market or auction-determined spread to LIBOR or the minimum spread to LIBOR. An FRN may provide, for example, two trigger levels (or strike prices) indicating that the FRN will earn a spread should the ECI Index fall between them at the end of the observation period.
In this embodiment, the inputs for an FRN order (which are some of the parameters associated with an FRl~ can be mapped or approximated, for example, at a built-in interface in a computer system, into desired payouts, selected outcomes and limits on the investment amounts for one or more digital options in an approximation set, so that the FRN order can be processed in the same demand~based market or auction along with direct digital option orders. Specifically;
each FRN order in terms of a note notional, a coupon or spread to LIBOR, and trigger level may be approximated with a LIBOR-bearing note for the notional amount (or a note for notional amount earning an interest rate set at LIBOR), and an embedded approximation set of one or more digital options.
As a result of the mapping or approximation, all orders of contingent claims (for example, digital option orders and FRN orders) are expressed in the same units or variables. Once all orders are expressed in the same units or variables, an optimization system, such as that described above in Section 7, determines an optimal investment amount and executed payout per order (if it expires in-the-money) and total amount invested in the demand-based market or auction. Then, at the interface, the parameters of the digital options in the approximation set corresponding to each FRN order are mapped back to parameters of the FRN
order. The coupon for the FRN (if above the minimum spread to LIBOR specified by the customer) is determined as a function of the digital options in the approximation set which are filled and the equilibrium price of the filled digital options in the approximation set, as determined by the entire demand-based market or auction. Thus, the FRN customer inputs certain FRN parameters, such as the minimum spread to LIBOR and the notional amount for the note, and the market or auction generates other FRN parameters for the customer, such as the coupon earned on the notional of the note if the note expires-in-the money.
- 22~ -The methods described above and in section 9.5 below set forth an example of the type of mapping that can be applied to the parameters of a variety of other structured products, to enable the structured products to be traded in a demand-based market or auction alongside other DBA.R
contingent claims, including, for example, digital options, thereby increasing the degree and variety of participation, liquidity and pricing efficiency of any demand-based market or auction.
The structured products include, for example, any existing or future financial products or instruments whose parameters can be approximated with the parameters of one or more DBAR
contingent claims, for example, digital options. The mapping in this embodiment can be used in combination with andlor applied to the other embodiments of the present invention.
9.5 Example: Ma~nin~ FRNs into Digital Option Space The following notation, figures and equations illustrate the mapping of ECI-linked FRNs into digital option space, or approximating the parameters of ECI-linked FRNs into parameters of an approximation set of one or more digital options, and can be applied to illustrate the mapping of ECI-linked swaps into digital option space.
9.5.1 Date and Timing Notation and Formulation ts: the premium settlement date for the direct digital option orders and the FRN orders, set at the same time or some time after the TED (or the end of the trading or auction period).
tE: the event outcome date or the end of the observation period (e.g., the date of that the outcome of the event is observed).
to: the option payout date tR: the coupon reset date, or the date when interest (spread to LIBOR, including, for example, spread plus LIBOR) begins to accrue on the note notional.
tN: the note maturity date, or the date for repayment of the note.
f the fraction of the year from date tR to date tN. This number may depend on the day-count convention used, e.g., whether the basis for the year is set at 365 days per year or 360 days per year. In this example, the basis for the year is set at 360 days, and f can be formulated as follows:
f _ number of daysbetween tR and tH 9.5.1A

As shown in FIG. 24, the market or auction in this example is structured such that the vote maturity date (tN) occurs on or after the option payout date (to) although, for example, the market or auction can be structured such that tN occurs before to.
Additionally, as illustrated, the option payout date (to) occurs on or after the end of the observation period (tE), and the end of the observation period (tE) occurs on or after the premium settlement date (ts).
The premium settlement date (ts), can occur on or after the end of the trading period for the demand-based market or auction. Further, the demand-based market or auction in this example is structured such that the coupon reset date (tR) occurs after the premium settlement date (ts) and before the note maturity date (t~,). However, the coupon reset date (also referred to, for example, as the "FRN Fixing Date") (t~ can occur at any time before the note maturity date (tN), and at any time on or after the end of the trading period or the premium settlement date (ts).
The coupon reset date (t~, for example, can occur after the end of the observation period (tE) and/or the option payout date (to). In this example, as shown in FIG. 24, the coupon reset date (t~ is set betweem the end of the observation period (tE) and the option payout date (to).
Similar to the discussion earlier in this specification in Section 1 that the duration of the trading period can be unknown to the participants at the time that they place their orders, any of the dates above can be pre-determined and known by the participants at the outset, or they can be unla~own to the participants at the time that they place their orders. The end of the trading period, the premium settlement date or the coupon reset date, for example, can occur at a randomly selected time, or could occur depending upon the occurrence of some event associated or related to the event of economic significance, or upon the fulfillment of some criterion. For example, for DBAR-enabled FRNs, the coupon reset date could occur after a certain volume, amount, or frequency of trading or volatility is reached in a respective demand-based market or auction. Alternatively, the coupon reset date could occur, for example, after an nth catastrophic natural event (e.g., a fourth hurricane), or after a catastrophic event of a certain magnitude (e.g., an earthquake of a magnitude of 5.5 or higher on the Richter scale), and the natural or catastrophic event can be related or unrelated to the event of economic significance, in this example, the level of the ECI.
9.5.2 Variables and formulation for demand-based market or auction E: Event of economic significance, in this example, ECI. The level of the ECI
observed on tE. This event is the same event for the FRN and direct digital option orders, referred to, e.g., as a "Trigger Level" for the FRN order, and as a "strike price" for the direct digital option order.
L: London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) from the date tR to tN, a variable that can be fixed; e.g., at.the start of the trading period.
S m: number of defined states, a natural number. Index letter i, i=1,2...,m.
In the example shown in Figure 9.2, for example, there can be,7 states depending on the outcome of an economic event: the level of the ECI on the event observation date.
ECI < 0.7;
0.7 < ECI < 0.8;
0.8<_ECI<0.9;
0.9 <_ ECI < 1.0;
1.0 < ECI < 1.1;
1.1 <_ ECI < 1.2; and ECI >_ 1.2.
nN: number of FRN orders in a demand-based market or auction, a non-negative integer.
Index letter jN, ji,~=1,2,...nN.
nD: number of direct digital option orders in a demand-based market or auction, a non-negative integer. Index letter jD, jD=1,2,...nD. Direct digital option orders, include, for example, orders which are placed using digital option parameters.
n~: number of digital option orders in an approximation set for a jN FRN
order. In this example, this number is known and fixed, e.g., at the start of the trading period, however as described below, this number can be determined during the mapping process, a non-negative integer. Index letter z, z = 1,2,..:n~.
n: number of all digital option orders in a demand-based market or auction, a non-negative integer. Index letter j, j=1,2,...n.
The above numbers relate to one another in a single demand-based market or auction as follows:
nN
n = ~ n,~( jN) + no 9~5.2A
JN=I
L: the rate of LIBOR from date tR to date tN
- 22~ -DFo: the discount factor between the premium settlement date and the option payout date (ts and to), to account for the time value of money. DFo can be set using LIBOR
(although other interest rates may be used), and equal to, for example, 1/[ 1 + (L*
portion of year from is to to)].
DFN: the discount rate between the premium settlement date and the note maturity date, is and tN. DFN can also be set using LIBOR (although other interest rates may be used), and equal to, for example, 1/[1 + (L* portion of year from is to tN)].
9:5.3 Variables and formulations for each note iN in demand-based market or auction A: notional or face amount or par of note.
U: minimum spread to LIBOR (a positive number) specified by customer for note, if the customer's selected outcome becomes the observed outcome of the event.
1 S Although both buy and sell FRN orders can be processed together with buy and sell direct digital option orders in the same demand-based market or auction, this example demonstrates the mapping for a buy FRN order.
NP: The profit on the note if one or more of the states corresponding to the selected outcome of the event is identified on the event outcome date as one or more of the states corresponding to the observed outcome (e.g., the selected outcome turns out to be the observed outcome, or the ECI reaching or surpassing the Trigger Level on the event outcome date), at the coupon rate, c, determined by this demand-based market or auction.
NP= Ax cx f x DFN 9.5.3A
NL: The loss on the note if none of the states corresponding to the selected outcome of the event is identified on the event outcome date as one more of the states corresponding to the observed outcome (e.g., the selected outcome does not turn out to be the observed outcome, or the ECI does not reach the Trigger Level on the event outcome date).
9.5.3B
N~= Ax Lx ~'x DFN

the equilibrium price of each of the digital options in the approximation set that are filled by the demand-based market of auction, the equilibrium price being determined by the demand-based market or auction.
All of the digital options in the approximation set can have, for example, the same payout profile or selected outcome, matching the selected outcome of the FRN.
Therefore, all of the digital options in one approximation set that are filled by the demand-based market or auction will have, for example, the same equilibrium price.
9.5.4 Variables and formulations for each digital option, z, in the approximation set of one or more di '~tal options for each note, jN_ in a demand-based market or auction 1 S wZ: digital option limit price for the z~' digital option in the approximation set. The digital options in the approximation set can be arranged in descending order by limit price. The first digital option in the set has the largest limit price. Each subsequent digital option has a lower limit price, but the limit price remains a positive number, such that wZ+1<wZ. The number of digital options in an approximation set can be pre-determined before the order is placed, as in this example, or can be determined during the mapping process as discussed below.
In this example, the limit price for the first digital option (z=1) in an approximation set for one FRN order (jN) can be determined as follows:
w1 = DFo * L / (U + L) 9.5.4A
The limit prices for subsequent digital options can be established such that the differences between the limit prices in the approximation set become smaller and eventually approach zero.
r2: requested or desired payout or notional for the z'" digital option in the approximation set.
- 22~ -c: coupon on the FRN, e.g., the spread to LIBOR on the FRN, corresponding to the coupon determined after the last digital option order in the approximation set is filled according to the methodology discussed, for example, in Sections 6 and 7.
The coupon, c, can be determined, for example, by the following:
DFo - ?G 9.5.4B
c= Lx w2 where wZ is the limit price of the last digital option order z in the approximation set of an FRN, jN, to be filled by the demand-based market or auction.
9.5.5 Formulations for the first dieital option. z =1. in the approximation set of one or more di -gital options for a note, jN in a demand-based market or auction: .
Assuming that the first digital option in the approximation set is the only digital option order filled by the demand-based market or auction (e.g., w2 < ~ < w~), then following equation 9.5.4B, then:
DFo - ~
c = L x 9.5.5A
w.
When the equilibrium price (for each of the filled digital options in the approximation set) is equal to the limit price for the first digital option in the approximation set, ~c = w,, the digital option profit is r1 (DFo- w,) and the digital option loss is r, w1. Equating the option's profit with the note's profit yields:
r1 (DFo - w1) = A * U * f * DFN 9.5.5B
Next, equating the option's loss with the note's loss yields:
r~wi=A*L*f *DFN 9.5.5C

The ratio of the option's profit to the option's-loss is equal to the ratio of the note's profit to the note's loss:
r,(DFo -w,) - AxUx f xDFN 9.5.5D
r,w, AxLx f xDFN
Simplifying this equation yields:
DFo - w, - _U 9,5,5E
w, L
~ DFo - U +1- L+U 9.5.5F
w, L L
Solving for w~ yields:
w1 = L ~ DFo 9.5.56 1 S Solving for r1 from Equation 9.5.5C yields:
r1=A*L*f *DFN/wl 9.5.5H
Substituting equation 9.5.5G for w1 into equation 9.5.5H yields the following formulation for the requested payout for the first digital option in the approximation set:
r -Axf xDFNx(L+U) 9.5.5I
DFo 9.5.6 Formulations for the second digital option, z = 2, in the approximation set of one or more digital options for a note, jN in a demand-based market or auction:
-22~-Assuming that the second digital option will be filled in the optimization system for the entire demand-based market or auction, the coupon earned on the note will be higher than the minimum spread to LIBOR specified by the customer, e.g., c > U.
S As stated above, the profit of the FRN is A * c * f * DFN and the loss if the states specified do not occur is A * L * f * DFN.
Now, since w~ is determined as set forth above, and wz can be set as some number lower than w1, assuming that the market or auction fills both the first and the second digital options and assuming that the equilibrium price is equal to the limit price for the second digital option (~ _ wz), the profits for the digital options if they expire in-the-money is equal to (r~+ rz) * (DFo- wz), and the option loss is equal to (r1+ rz)*wz. Equating the option's profit with the note's profit yields:
(r~+ rz) (DFo - wz) = A * c * f * DFN 9.5.6A
Equating the option's loss with the note's loss yields:
(r1 + rz) wz = A * L * f * DFN 9.5.6B
Solving for r2 yields:
rz = (A * L * f * DFN)/wz - r1 9.5.6C ' Assuming that the second digital option is the highest order filled in the approximation set by the demand-based market or auction, the ratio of the profits and losses of both of the options is approximately equal to the profits and losses of the FRN. This approximate equality is used to solve for the coupon, c. Simplifying the combination of the above equations relating to equating the profits and losses of both options to the profit and loss of the note, yields the following formulation for the coupon, c, earned on the note if the note expires in-the-money and wz > ~:
c = L * (DFo - ~) / wz 9.5.6D

9.5.7 Formulations for the z~' digital option in the approximation set of one or more digital options for a note iN in a demand-based market or auction:
The above description sets forth formulae involved with the first and second digital options in the approximation set. The following can be used to determine the requested payout for the z~' digital option in the approximation set. The following can also be used as the demand-based market's or auction's determination of a coupon for the FRN if the z'h digital option is the last digital option in the approximation set filled by the demand-based market or auction (for example, according to the optimization system discussed in Section 7), and if the FRN expires in-the-money.
The order of each digital option in the approximation set is treated analogously to a market order (as opposed to a limit order), where the price of the option, ~, is set equal to the limit price for the option, w2.
Thus, the requested payout for each digital option, r~, in the approximation set can be determined according to the following formula:
A x L x f x DFN Z-1 rz= -~Yx 9.5.7A
Wz X-j Note that the determination of the requested payout for each digital option, rz, is recursively dependent on the payouts for the prior digital options, r1, r2, ..., r2_1.
The number of digital option orders, nAD, used in an approximation set can be adjusted in the demand-based market or auction. For example, an FRN order.could be allocated an initial set number of digital option orders in the approximation set, and each subsequent digital option order could be allocated a descending limit order price as discussed above.
After these initial quantities are established for an FRN, the requested payouts for each subsequent digital option can be determined according to equation 9.5.7A. If the requested payout for the z'~ digital option in the approximation set approaches sufficiently close to zero, where z < n~, then the z"' digital option could be set as the last digital option needed in the approximation set, nAD would then equal z. The coupon determined by the demand-based market or auction becomes a function of LIl3~lZ, the discount factor between the premium settlement date and the option payment date, the equilibrium price, and the limit price of the last digital option in the approximation set to be filled by the optimization system for the demand-based market or auction discussed in Section 7:
c = L * (DFo - ~)/ wZ 9.5.7B
where w2 is the limit price of the last digital option order in the approximation set to be filled by the optimization system.
9.5.8 Numerical example of implementing formulations for the z~' di 'gital option in the approximation set of one or more di 'tal options for a note jj,~~ in a demand-based market or auction:
The following provides an illustration of a principal-protected Employment Cost Index-linked Floating Rate Note. In this numerical example, the auction premium settlement date is is October 24, 2001; the event outcome date tE, the coupon reset date tR, and the option payout date are all October 25, 2001; and the note maturity date tN is January 25, 2002.
In this case, the discount factors can be solved using a LIBOR rate L of 3.5%
and a basis of Actual number of days/360:
DFo = 0.999903 DFN = 0.991135 f= 0.255556 (There are 92 days of discounting between October 25, 2001 and January 25, 2002, which is used for the computation of f and DFN.) The customer or note holder specifies, in this example, that the FRN is a principal protected FRN, because the principal or par or face amount or notional is paid to the note holder in the event that the FRN expires out-of the-money. The customer specifies the trigger level of the ECI as 0.9% or higher, and the customer enters an order with a minimum spread of 150 basis points to LIBOR. This customer. will receive LIBOR plus 150 bps in arrears on 100 million USD
on.January 25, 2002, plus par if the ECI index fixes at 0.9% or higher. This customer will receive 100 million USD (since the note is principal protected) on January 25, 2002 if the ECI
index fixes at lower than 0.9%.
Following the notation for the variables and the formulation presented above, A = $100,000,000.00 (referred to as the par, principal, notional, face amount of the note) U = 0.015, i.e. bidder wants to receive a minimum of 150 basis points over LIBOR
The parameters for the first digital option in the approximation set for the demand-based market or auction are determined as follows by equation 9.5.4A:
w~ _ (0.035 / [0.035 + 0.015]) * 0.999903 = 0.70 It is reasonable to set wz, the limit price for the second digital option order in the approximation set to be equal to 0.69, therefore by equation 9.5.5H:
r1 = $100,000,000 * 0.035 * 0.255556 * 0.991135 / 0.70 = $1,266,500 The coupon, c, equals 0.01 S or 150 basis points, if the first digital option order becomes the only digital option order filled by the demand-based market or auction and the equilibrium price is equal to the limit price for the first digital option (~ = 0.7).
The.parameters for the second digital option in the approximation set for the demand-based market or auction are determined as follows, setting the limit price for this digital option to be less than the limit price for the first digital option, or wz = 0.69, then by equation 9.5.6C:
rz ' _ $100,000,000 * 0.035 * 0.255556 * 0.991135 / 0.69 - $1,266,500 _ $18,306 If ~, the equilibrium price of the digital option, is between 0.69 (wz) and 0.70 (w1), e.g., ~
= 0.695, then the note coupon, c = 0.0152 = 0.035*(0.999903-0.695)/0.70, or 152 bps spread to LIBOR by equation 9.5.5A. This becomes the coupon for the note if the demand-based market or auction only fills the first digital option order in the approximation set and if the demand-based market or auction sets the equilibrium price for the selected outcome equal to 0.695.
If ~, the equilibrium price of the digital option, is equal to 0.69 (wz), the coupon for the FRN becomes 157 basis points if the second digital option is the highest digital option order filled by the demand-based market or auction, by equation 9.5.6D:
c = 0.035 * (0.999903 - 0.69)/0.69 =0.0157 or 157 basis points The requested payouts for each subsequent digital option, and the subsequently determined coupon on the note (determined pursuant to the limit price of the last digital option in the approximation set to be filled by the demand-based market or auction and the equilibrium price for the selected outcome), are determined using equations 9.5.7A and 9.5.7B.
9.6 Conclusion These equations present one example of how to map FRNs and swaps into approximation sets comprised of digital options, transforming these FRNs and swaps into DBAR-enabled FRNs and swaps. The mapping can occur at an interface in a demand-based market or auction, enabling otherwise structured instruments to be evaluated and traded alongside digital options, for example, in the same optimization solution. As shown in FIG. 25, the methods in this embodiment can be used to create DBAR-enabled products out of any structured instruments, so that a variety of structured instruments and digital options can be traded and evaluated in the same efficient and liquid demand-based market or auction, thus significantly expanding the potential size of demand-based markets or auctions.
10. REPLICATING DERIVATIVES STRATEGIES USING DIGITAL OPTIONS
Financial market participants express market views and construct hedges using a number of derivatives strategies including vanilla calls and vanilla puts, combinations of vanilla calls and puts including spreads and straddles, forward contracts, digital .options, and knockout options.
This section shows how an entity or auction sponsor running a demand-based or DBAR auction can receive and fill orders for these derivatives strategies.
These derivatives strategies can be included in a DBAR auction using a replicating approximation, a mapping from parameters of, for example, vanilla options to digital options (also referred to as "digitals"), or, as described further in Section 1 l, a mapping from parameters of, for example, derivative strategies to a vanilla replicating basis. This mapping could be an automatic function built into a computer system accepting and processing orders in the demand-based market or auction. The replicating approximation permits or enables auction participants or customers to interface with the demand-based market or auction, side by side with customers who trade digital options, notes and swaps, as well as other DBAR-enabled products. This increases the overall liquidity and risk pricing efficiency of the demand-based market or auction by increasing the variety and number of participants in the market or auction.
Figure 26 shows how these ;options may be included in a DBAR auction with a digital replicating basis. Figure 29 shows how these options may be included in a DBAR auction with a vanilla replicating basis.
Offering such derivatives strategies in a DBAR auction provides several benefits for the customers. First, customers may have access to two-way markets for these derivatives strategies giving customers transparency not currently available in many derivatives markets. Second, customers will receive prices for the derivatives strategies based on the prices of the underlying digital claims, insuring that the prices for the derivatives strategies are fairly determined. Third, a DBAR auction may provide customers with greater liquidity than many current derivatives markets: in a DBAR auction, customers may receive a lower bid-ask spread for a given notional size executed and customers may be able to execute more notional volume for a given limit price.
Finally, offering these options provides customers the ability to enhance returns and achieve investment objectives in new ways.
In addition, offering such derivative strategies in a DBAR auction provides benefits for the auction sponsor. First, the auction sponsor will earn fee income from these orders. In addition, .
the auction sponsor has no price making requirements in a DBAR auction as prices are determined endogenously. In offering these derivatives strategies, the auction sponsor may be exposed to the replication profit and loss or replication P&L - the risk deriving from synthesizing the various derivatives strategies using only digital options.
However, this risk may be small in a variety of likely instances, and in certain instances described in Section 11, when derivative strategies are replicated into a vanilla replicating basis, this risk may be reduced to zero. Regardless, the cleared book from a DBAR auction, excluding this replication P&L and opening orders, will be risk-neutral and self hedging, a further benefit for the auction sponsor.
The remainder of section 10 shows how a number of derivatives strategies can be replicated in a DBAR auction. Section 10.1 shows-how to replicate a general class of derivatives strategies.
Next,.section 10.2 applies this general result for a variety of derivatives strategies. Section 10.3 shows how to replicate digitals using two distributional models for the underlying. Section 10.4 computes the replication P&L for a set of orders in the auction. Appendix 10A
summarizes the notation used in this section. Appendix l OB derives the mathematics behind the results in section 10.1 and 10.2. Appendix l OC derives the mathematics behind results in section 10.3.
10.1 The General Approach to Replicating Derivatives Strategies With Digital Options Let U denote the underlying measurable event and let S2 denote the sample space for U.
-23~-U may be a univariate random variable and thus S2 may be, for example, RI or R+. Otherwise U
may be a multidimensional random variable and S2 may be, for example, R°.
Assume that the sample space S2 is divided into S disjoint and non-empty subsets 521, 522, ..., S2s S such that S2;riS2~=Q5 for 1 <i <_Sand 1 Sj<_Sandi ~j lO.lA
S21 v S22 v . .. S2s = S2 10.1B
Thus, 521, 522, ..:, S2s represents a mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive division of S2.
Each sample space partition S2s can be associated with a state s. Namely, the underlying U E S2S
that means that state s has occurred, for s = 1, 2, ..., S. Thus, there are S
states in totality. It is worth noting that this definition of "state" differs from other definitions of "state" in that a "state" may represent only a specific outcome of a sample space: in this example embodiment, a "state" may represent a set of multiple outcomes.
Denote the probability of state s occurnng as ps for s = 1, 2, ..., S. Thus, ps---Pr[U: UE S2S)fors=1,2,...,S 10.1C
Assume that ps > 0 for s = l, 2, ..., S.
Consider a derivatives strategy that pays out d(U). This derivatives strategy will be referred to using the function d. The function d may be quite general: d may be a continuous or discontinuous function of U, a differentiable or non-differentiable function of U. For example, in the case where a derivatives strategy based on digitals is being replicated, the function d is discontinuous and non-differentiable.
Let as denote the digital replication for state s, the series of digitals that replicate the derivatives strategy d. Let C' denote tlae replication P~cf, to the auction sponsor. if C' is g~asitive (negatgve~, then the auction sponsor receives a profit (a loss) from the replication of the strategy. The replication P&L to the auction sponsor C is given by the following formula for a buy order of d s C --- ~ I[U E S2, ][as - d (U) + e] 10.1D
s=1 where _e = min E[d (U) ( U E S2s ] 10.1 E
s=1,2,...,5 In this case, a denotes the minimum conditional expected value of d(U) within state s. For intuition as to why C depends on e, consider the simple example where d(U~ (a constant) for all values of U. In this case, of course, the replication P&L should be zero since there are no digitals required to replicate the strategy d. It can be shown that a =~ and C
equals 0 for as =0 for s=1, 2, ..., 5 using equation 10.1D. Thus, a is required in equation 10.1D to make C, the 1 S replication P&L, zero in this case.
The replication P&L for a sell of d is the negative of the replication P&L of a buy of d s C---~I[UES2J][d(U)-as-e] 10.1F

In equation 10.1F, as represents the replicating digital for a buy order.
Let a = max E[d (U) ~ U E S2f ] 10.16 s=1,2,...,5 As defined in 10.1 G, a denotes the maximum conditional expected value of d(U) within state s.
?3~ -This example embodiment restricts these parameters 0<_e< a<oo 10.1H
so that the conditional expected value of d is bounded above and below. Note that this condition can be met when the function d itself is unbounded, as is the case for many derivatives strategies such as vanilla calls and vanilla puts.
Values of (a~, a2, ..., as 1, as) are selected in this example embodiment as follows Objective: Choose (al, a2, ...,,as_1, as) to minimize Yar[C] subject to E[C] =

'In words, the a's are selected so that the auction sponsor has the minimum variance of replication P&L subject to the constraint that the expected replication P&L is zero.
Under these conditions, the general replication theorem in appendix l OB
proves that the replication digitals are a, = E[d (U) ~ U E SZs ] - a for s= 1, 2, . . ., S 10.1I
The replication P&L and the infimum replication P&L can be computed as follows s C = ~I[U E S2s ](E[d (U) ~ U E S2s ] - d(U)) 10.1J
inf C = min ~ inf (E[d (U) ~ U E S2s ] - d (U))~ 10.1 K
s=1,2,...,5 UsS7, The infimum is significant because it represents the worst possible loss to the auction sponsor. If d is bounded over the sample space, then this infimum will be finite, but in the case where d is unbounded this infimum may be unbounded below.

For an order to sell the derivatives strategy d, the general replication theorem in appendix l OB
shows that the replicating digitals for selling d are as = e- E[d (U) ~ U E S2, ] for s =1, 2, ..., S 10.1L
The replication P&L and the infimum replication P&L for a sell of d can be computed as follows s C = ~ I [U E S2, ] (d (U) - E[d (U) ~ U E S2, ]) 10.1 M
s=~
inf C = min ~ inf (d (U) - E[d (U) ~ U E S2, ])~ 10.1 N
s=1,2,...,5 Uefl, Note that the replication P&L for a sell of d is the negative of the replication P&L for a buy of d.
Similarly, the infimum replication P&L for a sell of d is the negative of the infimum replication P&L for a buy of d.
The variance of the replication P&L is the same for a buy or a sell S
Yar[C] _ ~ p,Yar[d (U) ~ U E S2, ] lo.lo 3=I
It is worth noting that for both buys of d and sells of d that min(al, a2, ..., as_~, as)=0 10.1P
Thus, all the a's are non-negative and at least one of the a's is exactly zero.
The example embodiment described above restricts the parameters as follows 0_<e< a<oo 10.1Q

Equation 10.1Q requires the conditional expected value of d(U) to be bounded both above and below. Other example embodiments may relax this assumption. For example, values of (a~, a2, ..., as_l, aS) could be selected such that S
Objective: Choose (al, a2, ..., aS 1, as) to minimize E[median~C~] subject to median[C] = 0 In this case, the a's are selected so that the auction sponsor has the lowest average absolute replication P&L subject to the constraint that the median replication P&L is zero. This objective function allows a solution for the (al, a2, ..., as_~, as) where the conditional expected values of d(U) can be unbounded.
In addition to.replicating these derivatives strategies, one can determine pricing on a derivatives 1 S strategy based on the replicating digitals. In an example embodiment, the price of a derivatives s strategy d will be DF x ~ ag ps , where the a's represent the replicating digitals for the strategy d s=~
and DF represents the discount factor (which is based on the funding rate between the premium settlement date and the notional settlement date). In the case where the discount factor DF
s equals 1, the price of a derivatives strategy d will be ~ a, p, .
s=1 In an example embodiment, the auction sponsor may assess a fee for a customer transaction thus increasing the customer's price for a buy and decreasing the customer's price for a sell. This fee may be based on the replication P&L associated with each strategy, charging possibly an increasing amount based on but not limited to the variance of replication P&L
or the infimum replication P&L for a derivatives strategy d.
10.2 Application of General Results to Special Cases This section begins by examining the special case where the underlying U is one-dimensional.
Section 10.2.1 introduces the general result and then section 10.2.2 provides specific examples for a one-dimensional underlying. Section 10.2.3 provides results for a two-dimensional underlying and section 10.2.4 provides results for higher dimensions.
10.2.1 General Result S
For a one-dimensional underlying U, let the strikes be denoted as k,, k2, ..., ks ~. Let the strikes be in increasing order, that is, k1 < kZ < k3 < ... < ks_2 < ks_, 10.2.1 A
For rotational purposes, let ko = -oo and let ks = +oo. Therefore, S21= [ U: ko <_ U< k1]=[ U-. U< k1] 10.2.1B
S2S = [ U: ks 1 < U < ks]=[ U: ks_1 <_ U J 10.2.1C
and thus S2 = R1 and S2S = [U: ks_1 S U< ks], s=1, 2, ..., S 10.2.1D
In other example embodiments S2 = R+, which may be useful for example if the underlying U
represents the price of an instrument that cannot be negative.
The replicating digitals for a buy for a one-dimensional underlying is as =E[d(U)~ks_, 5U<ks]-efors=1,2, ...,5 10.2.1E
where e= min E[d(U)~k,_, __<U<kfJ 10.2.1F
s=t,z,...,s - 2~0 The replication P&L and the infimum replication P&L are s C = ~I[k,_, <_ U < ks ](E[d (U) ~ ks_, 5 U < kJ ] - d (U)) 10.2.16 s=1 S inf C = min ~ inf (E[d (U) ~ kJ_, < U < kS ] - d (U))J 10.2.1 H
s=1,2,._.,S k,_,sU<k, For sells of the derivatives strategy d the replicating digitals are aJ =e-E[d(U)~k,_, <_U<kJ]fors=1,2,...,5 10.2.1I
where a = max E[d (U) ~ ks_, < U < k, ] 10.2.1) s=1,2,...,5 Further, the replication P&L and the infimum replication P&L are s C = ~ I[k,_, S U < kJ ](d (U) - E[d (U) ~ ks_, <- U < ks ]) 10.2.1K
s=1 inf C = min ~ inf (d (U) - E[d (U) ~ kJ_, <_ U < kf ])~ 10.2.1L
s=1,2,...,5 kf_~SU<k, The variance of replication P&L for both buys and sells of d is s Yar[CJ = ~ psYar[d (U) ~ ks_, -< U < ks ] 10.2.1M
J=I
Section 10.2.2 uses these formulas to derive results for derivatives strategies on one-dimensional underlyings.
- 24 fi -10.2.2 Replicating Derivatives Strategies with a One-Dimensional Underlying This section uses the formulas from section 10.2.1 to compute replicating digitals (al, a2, ..., ail, as) for both buys and sells of the following derivatives strategies: digital options (digital calls, digital puts, and range binaries), vanilla call options and vanilla put options, call spreads and put spreads, straddles, collared straddles, forwards, collared forwards, fixed price digital options, and fixed price vanilla options.
In addition to these derivatives strategies, an auction sponsor can offer derivatives based on these techniques, including but not limited to derivatives that are quadratic (or higher power) functions i of the underlying, exponential functions of the underlying, and butterfly or combination strategies that generally require the buying and selling of three of more options.
Replicating Digital Calls, Digital Puts and Range Binaries A digital call expires in-the-money and pays out a specified amount if the underlying U is greater than or equal to a threshold value. For notation, let v be an integer such that 15 v <_ S 1. Then the d function for a digital call with a strike price of kv is 0 for U < kv d (U) = 10.2.2A
1 for k,; S U
For a buy order of a digital call with a strike price of k,, the replicating digitals are Ofors=1,2, ...,v as = 10.2.2B
lfors=v+l,v+2, ...,5 For a sell order of a digital call with a strike price of k,, the replicating digitals are _ Ifors=1,2,...,v a$ - 10.2.2C
Ofors=v+l,v+2,...,5 -2~2-A digital put pays out a specific quantity if the underlying is strictly below a threshold on expiration. Let v be an integer such that 1<_ v 5 S-1. For a digital put, d is defined as lforU<k d (U) _ " 10.2.2D
0 for ky _< U
For a buy order of a digital put with a strike price of k,, the replicating digitals are 1 fors=1,2,...,v a, = 10.2.2E
0 fors=v+l,v+2,...,5 For a sell order of a digital put with a strike price of k,, the replicating digitals are _ Ofors=l, 2,...,v as lfors=v+l,v+2, ...,5 10.2.2F
A range binary strategy pays out a specific amount if the underlying is within a specified range.
Let v and w be integers such that 1 S v < w <_ S-1. Then the range binary strategy can be represented as 0 for U < ky d(U)= lfor ky<_U<k", 10.2.2G
0 for kw <_ U
For a buy order of a range binary with strikes k" and kw the replicating digitals are Ofors=1,2,...,v as= lfors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.2.2H
Ofors=w+l,w+2,...,5 For a sell order of a range binary with strikes k" and kw the replicating digitals are lfors=1,2,...,v as= Ofors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.2.2I
lfors=w+l,w+2,...,5 For these three digital strategies, it can be shown that a = 0 and a =1. For buys and sells of digital calls, digital puts, and range binaries, the replication P&L is zero and the variance of the S replication P&L is zero.
Replicating Vanilla Call Options and Vanilla Put Options This section describes how to replicate vanilla calls and vanilla puts. Though financial market participants will often just refer to these options as simply calls and puts, the modifier vanilla is used here to differentiate these calls and puts from digital calls and digital puts.
Let v denote an integer such that 15 v S S 1. A vanilla call pays out as follows OforU<k"
1 S d (U) = U - k~ for ky 5 U 10.2.2) For a buy order for a vanilla call with strikes of k,, the replicating digitals are Ofors=1,2,...,v aJ = 10.2.2K
E[U~ks_,<_U<ks]-k,,fors=v+l,v+2,...,5 For a sell order for a vanilla call with strike ky the replicating digitals are E[U~ks_,<_U]-k,,fors=1,2,...,v as = 10.2.2L
E[U~ks-,-_<U]-E[U~ks_,<U<ks] fors=v+l,v+2,...,5 Note that for a vanilla call, a = 0 and a = E[U ~ ks-, -< U] - ky .

Figures 27A, 27B and 27C show the functions d and C for a vanilla call option for an example that is discussed in further detail in sections 10.3.1 and 10.3.2.
For a vanilla put, let v be an integer such that 1 S v -< S 1. A vanilla put pays out as follows k -U forU<k d(U) _ " " 10.2.21VI
0 fork" <-U
For a buy order for a vanilla put with strikes of k" the replicating digitals are k"-E[U~ks-,<-U<k,) fors=1,2,...,v as = 10.2.2N
0 fors=v+l,v+2,...,5 For a sell order for a vanilla put with a strike of k" the replicating digitals are E[U~k,_, __<U<k,)-E[U~U<k,) forS=1,2,...,v as = 10.2.20 k"-E[U~U<k,) fors=v+l,v+2,...,w Note that for a vanilla put, a = 0 and a = k" - E[U ~ U < k, ) .
It is worth noting that the replication P&L for a buy or sell of a vanilla call and vanilla put can be unbounded because these options can pay aut unbounded amounts.
Replicating Call Spreads and Put Spreads A buy of a call spread is the simultaneous buy of a vanilla call and the sell of a vanilla call. Let v and w be integers such that 1 <_ v < w <- S 1. Then d for a call spread is 0 for U < k"
d (U) = U - k" for k" <_ U < kw 10.2.2P
kw - k" for kw 5 U

For a buy order for a call spread with strikes of ky and k", the replicating digitals are 0 fors=1,2,...,v as = E[U~ks-I SU <k,J-ky fors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.2.2Q
kW - k,, fors=w+l,w+2,...,5 For a sell order for a call spread with strikes of kV and 1~, the replicating digitals are kw - ky for s =1, 2, ..., v as = kW-E[U~ks_, __<U<ks) fors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.2.28 0 fors=w+l,w+2,...,S
If strike 1~,, is high enough, a call spread will approximate a vanilla call.
However, note that the replication P&L for a call spread is always bounded, whereas the replication P&L for a vanilla call can be infinite.
Figures 28A, 28B and 28C show the functions d and C for a call spread for an example that is discussed in further detail in sections 10.3.1 and 10.3.2.
A buy of a put spread is the simultaneous buy of a vanilla put and a sell of a vanilla put. Let v and w be integers such that 1 <- v < w < S 1. Then for a put spread the function d is kW - k,, for U < ky d (U) = kW - U for ky S U < k", 10.2.25 0 for kW S U
For a buy order for a put spread with strikes of k,, and kw the replicating digitals are kW - k,, for s =1, 2, ..., v as = kw-E[U~ks-, SU<ks] fors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.2.2T
0 fors=w+l,w+2,...,5 -24~-For a sell order for a put spread with strikes of k,, and kW the replicating digitals are 0 fors=1,2,...,v as= E[U~k,_,<_U<kJ]-ky fors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.2.2U
kW - k,, for s = w+ 1, w + 2, ..., S
For a strike 1~, low enough, this put spread will approximate a vanilla put.
However, note that the replication P&L for a put spread is always bounded, whereas the replication P&L for a vanilla put can be infinite.
For call spreads and put spreads note that a = 0 and a = kW - k,, .
Replicating Straddles and Collared Straddles A buy of a straddle is the simultaneous buy of a call and a put both with identical strike prices.
A buy of a straddle is generally a bullish volatility strategy, in that the purchaser profits if the 1 S outcome is very low or very high. Using digitals one can construct straddles as follows.
Let v be an integer such that 2 < v <_ S 2. For a straddle, the payout d is k -U forU<k d (U) _ " '' 10.2.2V
U - k,, for k,, <- U
For a buy order of a straddle with strike k,, the replicating digitals are k,, - E[U ~ ks_, 5 U < kJ ] -_e for s = l, 2, ..., v a, = 1 0.2.2W
E[U~ks_, <U<k,]-ky-a fors=v+l,v+2,...,5 where a = min[k" - E[U ~ k,,_, <- U < ky ], E[U ~ k,, <- U < ky+, ] - k,, ] 10.2.2X

For the sell of a straddle with strike k,,, the replicating digitals are e-ky+E[U~ks_, <_U<ks] fors=1,2,...,v a, = 10.2.2Y
e-E[U~ks-, <-U<ks]+ky fors=v+1,v+2,...,S
S
where a = max[ky - E[U ~ U < k, ], E[U ~ kS_, <- U] - k,, ] 10.2.22 Note that, buys and sells of straddles may have unbounded replication P&L
since the underlying vanilla calls and vanilla puts themselves can have unbounded payouts.
As opposed to offering straddles, an auction sponsor may instead wish to offer customers a straddle-like instrument with bounded replication P&L, referred to here as a collared straddle.
Let v be an integer such that 2 < v 5 S 2. For a collared straddle let kv-k, forU<k, ky-U fork,<U<k"
d (U) = U - k" for ky <- U < ks_, 10.2.2AA
ks-, - kv for ks_, 5 U
For a buy order of a collared straddle with strike k,, the replicating digitals are ky-k,-a fors=1 k~-E[U~ks_, <_U<k$]-a fors=2,3,...,v as = - 10.2.2AB
E[U~k$_,SU<ks] -ky-a fors=v+l,v+2,...,S-1 ks_, - ky - a for s = S
where a is as before. For a sell order of a collared straddle with strike k"
the replicating digitals are e-kv+k, fors=1 e- k,, + E[U ~ kJ_1 <- U < kJ ] for s = 2, 3, ..., v as = 10.2.2AC
e-E[U~ks-, <-U<k,]+ky fors=v+l,v+2,...,5-1 e- ks_1 +. ky for s = S
where e=max[ks ~-k,,, kv k1].
S
As observed above, the replication P&L for this collared straddle is bounded, since it comprises the buy of a call spread and the buy of a put spread.
Replicating Forwards and Collared Forwards A forward pays out based on the underlying as follows d (U) = U 10.2.2AD
Therefore, for a buy order for a forward, the replicating digitals are as = E[U ~ k,_, 5 U < ks ] - E[U ~ U < k, ] for s =1, 2, ..., S 10.2.2AE
For a sell order for a forward, note the replicating digitals are a, =E[U~ks-, SU]-E[U~k,_, -U<ks] fors=1,2,...,5 10.2.2AF
Note that for a forward, a = E[U ~ U < k, ] and a = E[U ~ ks_, 5 U] .
Note that buys and sells of forwards can have unbounded replication P&L.
- 24~ -To avoid offering a forward with possibly unbounded replication P&L, the auction sponsor may offer a collared forward strategy with maximum and minimum payouts. For a collared forward k, for U < k, d (U) = U for k, <- U < kS-, 10.2.2AG
ks_, for ks_, < U
S
Note that e=kl and a = ks_, . Therefore, for a buy order for a collared forward, the replicating digitals are 0 fors=1 a, = E[U~ks_, <-U <kf]--k, fors=2,3,...,5-1 10.2.2AH
ks-,-k,fors=S
Note that the formulas for the a's are identical to those for a call spread with strikes of k1 and ks 1.
For a sell order for a collared forwarded ks-, - k, for s =1 a, _ ks_, - E[U ~ k,_, _< U < ks ] for s = 2, 3, ..., S -1 10.2.2AI
for s=S
Note that buys and sells of collared forwards, by construction, have bounded replication P&L.
Replicating Digital Options With a Maximum Fixed Price An auction sponsor can offer customers derivatives strategies where the customer specifies the maximum price to pay and then the strike is determined such that the customer pays as close as possible to but no greater than the specified price. Offering these derivatives strategies will allow a customer to trade such market strategies as the over-under strategy, where the customer receives a notional quantity equal to twice the price. As another example, a customer could trade a digital option with a specific payout of say 5 to 1. These derivatives strategies may provide the customer with an option with a strike that may not be available for other options in the auction.
For example, in general the option strikes on these strategies may be different from k~, k2, ..., ks ~
thus these derivative strategies provide the customers with customized strikes.
For illustrative purposes, assume that the customer desires a digital call option and specifies a price p=, which is the maximum price the customer is willing to pay for this option. Based on this p=, the strike k* is then determined such that k* is as low as possible such that the price of the digital call option is no greater thanp*. To implement an over-under strategy, the customer will submit a price ofp*~.S and to request a digital option with a S to 1 payout, the customer will submit a price ofp* =0.2.
This digital call option pays out 1 if the underlying U is greater than or equal to k. and zero.
otherwise. Therefore, 0 forU<k, d (U) = 10.2.2AJ
1 for k, < U
Assume that the digital call option struck at k"_~ has a price less than p*
and the digital call option struck at k,, has a price greater than or equal to p* and assume that 1<_ v <_ S 2. Therefore, kv_1 < k* < k,, 10.2.2AK
In the special case where the price of the digital call option struck at k~
equals exactly p*, then k*=
k" and the replicating digitals for this derivatives strategy are the replicating digitals for the digital call struck at k,,.
The expected value of the digital call option payout is E~d(U)~= Pr[k. <_ U] 10.2.2AL
- 2~1 -The auction sponsor will set k~ such that the expected payout on the option is as close to as possible but no greater than p=. Namely, k~ is the minimum value such that Pr[I~ <_ U] 5 p. 10.2.2AM
Therefore, in terms of the states s, the payout of the option strategy is 0 fors=1,2,...,v-1 0 fors=v andU<k.
d (U) = 1 for s = v and k, _< U 10.2.2AN
1 fors=v+l,v+2,...,5 Now, as for the previously considered digital options e=0 and a =1. By the general replication theorem of appendix lOB then Ofors=1,2,...,v-1 as - Pr[k. <_ U < k,, ] for s = v 10.2.2A0 Pv lfors=v+l,v+2,...,5 The price of this digital call option can be computed as Pr[k. <_ U < kY ]
asps = Pv + ~ Ps s=1 Pv s=v+1 S
=Pr[k.SU<kY]+ ~ps s=v+I
= Pr[k. < U]
~ P~ 10.2.2AP

where the last step follows by how k= is constructed.
By the general replication theorem of appendix l OB, the sell of this strategy has the following replicating digitals 1 fors=1,2,...,v-1 a = 1 _ Pr[k. 5 U < kv J for s = v 10.2.2AQ
s Py 0 fors=v+l,v+2,...,S
It is worth noting that the infimum replication P&L for buys and sells of this strategy is finite.
Replicating Vanilla Options With a Fixed Price This section shows how to replicate a vanilla option with a fixed price. For illustrative purposes, assume that a customer requests to purchase a vanilla call with a price of p=.
Let k= denote the strike price of the option to be determined to create an option with a price ofp=. This vanilla call pays out as follows OforU<k.
d (U) = U _ ~ for k. 5 U 10.2.2AR
Assume that the price of a vanilla call with a strike of ky_1 is less thanp=
and that the price of a vanilla call with a strike of k,, is greater than or equal to p=. Thus, k"_, < k= S k,, 10.2.2AS
In the special case that the price of a vanilla call with a strike of k" is exactly p= then set k= = k,.
and the replicating digitals are the replicating digitals for a vanilla call.
Now, the expected value of the payout on this option is E~d (U)~ = E[U - k. ~ k, S U < k" ] Pr[k, 5 U < k" ]
s + ~ E[U - k. ~ ks-, S U < ks ] ps 10.2.2AT
s=v+t Set k= such that the expected payout on the option equals the price p=.
Namely, that p. = E[U - k. ~ k. 5 U < k,, ] Pr[k. S U < k,, s + ~ E[U - k, ~ k~_t 5 U < ks ] p, 10.2.2AU
s=y+t Solving for k= in this equation may require a one-dimensional iterative search.
Therefore, the derivatives strategy d in terms of states is 0 fors=1,2,...,v-1 0 fors=v andU<k.
d(U)= U-k, fors=v and k.SU 10.2.2AV
U-k, fors=v+l,v+2,...,S
Note that e=0 and a = E[U - k. ~ ks-, <_ U] . Therefore, by the general replication theorem of appendix IOB, the replicating digitals are Ofors=1,2,...,v-1 Pr[k. <_ U < ky](E[U - k, ~ k. S U < kv]) for s = v 10.2.2AW
PY
E[U-k.~ks-,<_U<ks]for s=v+l,v+2,...,S
To check that the replication of this derivatives strategy has a price ofp=, note that the price is s Pr[k.<-U<k,,](E[U-k~~k~SU<k"]) s asps = P~ + ~ PsE[U - k~ ~ ks-t ~ U < ks ]
s=~ Pv s=v+t
-25~-s =Pr[k. <-U<ky]E[U-k. ~k: SU<k,,]+ ~psE[U-k. ~ks-, SU<k,]
sw+~
= p. 10.2.2AX
For sells of this strategy, E[U-k. ~ks-, <_U]fors=1,2,...,v-1 as = E[U - k, ~ ks_, <- U] - Pr[k, S U < ky ] (E[U - k. ~ k. <- U < k,, ]) for s = v 10.2.2A~
P,, E[U-k. ~kJ-, -_<U]-E[U-k, ~ks_, <-U<ks]for s=v+l,v+2,...,5 Using this approach, an auction sponsor can use digital options to replicate a vanilla call option with a fixed delta. In this way, a customer can request a vanilla call option with a 25 delta or a 50 delta since the price of a vanilla call option is a one-to-one function of the delta of a vanilla call option (with the option maturity, the forward of the underlying, the implied volatility as a differentiable function of strike, and the interest rate all fixed and Down).
In addition to replicating vanilla call options, auction sponsors can use this replication approach to offer fixed price options for, but not limited to, vanilla puts, call spreads, and put spreads.
Summary of Replication P&L
Table 10.2.2-1 shows the replication P&L for these different derivatives strategies discussed above.

Table 10.2.2-1: Replication P&L for different derivative strategies.
Derivative Strategy Replication P&L

A digital call 0 A digital put 0 A range binary 0 A vanilla call Possibly Infinite A vanilla put Possibly Infinite A call spread Finite A put spread Finite A straddle Possibly Infinite A collared straddle Finite A forward Possibly Infinite A collared forward Finite A digital call -with Finite maximum price A vanilla call with. Possibly Infinite a fixed price 10.2.3 Replicating Derivatives Strategies When the Underlying Is Two-Dimensional Assume that the underlying U is two-dimensional and let Ul and UZ denote one-dimensional random variables as follows U= (Ui, UZ) 10.2.3A
Assume that derivatives strategies will be based on a total of S1-1 strikes for U1 denoted k; ,kz,k3,...,ks,_, , and assume option strategies will be based on a total of SZ-1 strikes for U2 denoted k; , k2 , k3 , ..., k T_, . Note that a superscript of 1 is used to denote strikes associated with UI and a superscript of 2 is used to denote strikes associated with U2.
Further, assume that k; < k2 < k; < ... < ks~-2 < ks~_, 10.2.3B
-25~-k; < k2 < k3 < ... < ksz_Z < ksz-, 10.2.3C
Thus, the strikes are in ascending order based on the subscript. Further, for notational convenience, for Ul let ko = -oo and let ks~ = oo . For UZ, let ko = --oo and k 2 = oo . These four variables do not represent actual strikes but will be useful in representing formulas later.
For terminology, let state (i, j) denote an outcome U such that [U:k,', 5U, <k,')n[U:k~ , __<UZ <k~] 10.2.3D
for i=1, 2, ..., S1 and j=l, 2, ..., S2.
Let p;; denote the probability of state (i, j) occurring. That is p~ =Pr[k,', SU, <k,.' &k~_1 <_U2 <k~] 10.2.3E
for i=1, 2, ..., S~ and j=l, 2, ..., SZ. Let a;~ denote the replicating quantity of digitals for state (i, j).
The remainder of the section will use this notation tailored to this two-dimensional case.
However, it is worth mapping this notation into the general notation from section 10.2.1. In this case one can enumerate a mapping from state (i, j) into state s as follows s = (i-1)SZ +j for i=1, 2, ..., Sl and j=1, 2, ..., S2 10.2.3F
This defines s for s --.1, 2, ..., S where S = S1 x S2. Then S2, =[U:k;', <U, <k,.',k~-, <U2 <k~] 10.2.36 PS =P~i 10.2.3H

as = a~ 10.2.3I
for s = (i-1 )S2 + j.
The general replication theorem from appendix l OB can be used to derive results for this two-dimensional case. The digital replication for a buy is a~ =E[d(U,,U2)~k,.'-, __<U, <k,! &k~_, SU2 <k~] -a 10.2.3) for i=1, 2, ..., Sl and j=1, 2, ..., S~
where r e=i=,mm~ E[d(U,,Uz)I k,.'_, SU, <k' &k~_, SU2 <k~] 10.2.3K
=t,2,...,s~
The replication P&L and the infimum replication P&L for a buy is given by s, s2 C-~~I[k', ~U, <ki']I[k;-, ~U2 <k;]X
t=t ;=t x(E[d(U"U2)~k.', SU, <k.'&k~-, <_U2 <k~)-d(U,,U2)) 10.2.3L
inf C = min ~ inf ~ (E[d (U, , U2 ) ~ k,' , < U, < k,.' & k j-, S U2 < k~ ) -d (U,, U2 )~
i=1,2,...,5, k1_, 5U, <k, j=1,2,...,Sz kz_ SU <kz p z 10.2.3M
For sells of the strategy based on d a~ = e- E[d (U) ~ k,.'_, < U, < k; & k~ , _< U2 < k~ ]
fori=1,2,...,S,andj=1,2,...,52 10.2.3N
-25~-where e= max E[d(U,,U2)~k,.', SU, <k,.' &kj_, SU2 <kl] 10.2.30 i=I,z,...,s, j=1,2,...,Sz S The replication P&L, and the infimurn replication P&L are s, s~
C=~~1[k~ I ~U~ <k1]~k;_, <U2 <k~]x r=I i_1 x(d(U"U2)-E[d(U,,Ui)Ik,.'_, SUB <lct&k~_, <U2 <k~]]) 10.2.3P
inf C = min ~ inf ~ (d (U, , U2 ) - E[d (U, , U2 ) ~ k,.'_, < U, < k.' & k~ _, < U2 < k j ]) i=1 2 ...,5, k~_, SU, <k, J=1,2,...,Sz k2 SU <kz J~ z J
10.2.3Q
The variance of the replication P&L for both buys and sells of d is s, s2 Yar[C]=~~p;JVar[d(U,,U2)~k;', 5U, <k,.' &k~_, SU2 <k~] 10.2.3R
r_1 W
Replicating Derivatives Strategies that Depend Upon Only One Underlying With a two-dimensional underlying (or equivalently option strategies based on two univariate random variables), an auction sponsor can offer customers option strategies described above from the one-dimensional underlying including but not limited to call spreads and put spreads.
Including these univariate vanilla options with a two-dimensional underlying will help aggregate liquidity in these markets as it allows customers to take positions based on U, individually, UZ
individually, or UI and UZ jointly all in the same auction.

To see how this can be done, as an illustration consider a call spread with strikes ky and kW . To price a call spread on Ul in this framework define 0 if U, < k,', d(U,,UZ)= U,-kyifkySU, <kw 10.2.35 k", - ky if k,'~ 5 U, S
Note that this function does not depend upon UZ in any way. For a buy of d in this case, the replicating digitals are Ofori=1,2,...,vand j=1,2,...,52 E[U, ~k', <U, <k; &k~ , <-Uz <kl]-k,', a;; _ 10.2.3T
fori=v+l,v+2,...,wand j=1,2,...,52 k,'~ - kV for i = w + 1, w + 2, ..., S, and j =1, 2, ..., Sz Also, for a sell order on d k",-ky fori=1,2,...,vand j=1,2,...,Sz kW - E[U, ~. k,.'-, <- U, < k,' & k2 _<< U < k? ]
a.; _ '-' 2 ' 10.2.3U
fort=v+l,v+2,...,wand j=1,2,...,Sz Ofor i=w+l,w+2,...,S,andj=1,2,...,52 For a specific i, consider the case where E[U, ~ k,'-, <- U, < k; & k~-, S UZ < k~ ] = E[U, ~ k;'-, <- U, < k; ] 10.Z.3V
for all j, i.e. if the conditional expectation of U~ given i and j is equal to the conditional expectation of Ul given i. This condition will be satisfied, for instance, if U~ and U2 are independent random variables. Then under this condition the formula for a;~
for buys and sells simplifies to the replication formulas for a call spread in one-dimension discussed in section 10.3.
- 26~ -Specifically, equation 10.2.3T simplifies to equation 10.2.2Q, and equation 10.2.3U simplifies to equation 10.2.28.
Replicating Derivatives Strategies on the Sum, Difference, Product and Quotient of Two Variables To create an option on the sum of two variables, set the function d as follows 0 if U,+UZ<k d(U,,Uz) = 10.2.3W
U,+UZ-kifk<_U,+U2 Assume that the strikes are all non-negative and the underlyings are also non-negative (so ko = 0 and ko = 0) and fiu-ther assume that k > k; + k,2 . In this case, for a buy of d a~ = E(max(U, + UZ - k,0) ~ k, <_ U, < k; & k~_, <- UZ < k~ J
10.2.3X
for i =1, 2, ..., S, and j =1, 2, ..., S2 Note that several values of a;~ will likely be zero in this case. For example, since k > k; + k; , then in state (1, 1) Ul+U2 < k so all=0. This implies that e=0. For a sell of d, then, a;~ = a - E[max(U, + UZ - k,0) ~ k. , _< U, < k; & k~_y <_ UZ < k~ J
10.2.3Y
fori=1,2,...,5, and j=1,2,...,S2 where e=E[U,+Uz-k~ks~_, <_U, &k2_, <-UZ] 10.2.32 Creating options on the sum of two variables will be useful to the auction sponsor. For example, Ut could be the number of heating degree days for January and UZ could be tine number of - 2b~ -heating degree days for February. Then the sum of these two variables U~+UZ is the number of heating degree days for January and February combined.
In a similar fashion an auction sponsor can offer derivatives strategies on the d~erence between S Ul and'U2. For instance, U~ could be the level of target federal funds at the end of the next federal reserve open market committee meeting and U2 could be level of target federal funds after the following such meeting. Thus an option on the difference U2 - Ul would relate to what happens between the end of the 1S' meeting and the end of the 2"d meeting. In addition, derivatives strategies on differences can be applied to the interest rate market. If U~ is a two-year interest rate at the close at a certain date in the future and U2 is a ten-year interest rate at the close at the same future date, then the difference represents the slope of the interest rate curve at the future specified date. If Ul is the yield on a 10-year reference Treasury at the close at a certain date in the future and U2 is the 10-year swap rate at the close at the same date in the future, then the difference represents the swaps spread.
In a similar fashion, an auction sponsor can create options on the product of two variables. For example if Ul is the exchange rate of dollars per euro and UZ is the exchange rate of yen per dollar, then Ul x U2 is the exchange rate of yen per euros.
Further, an auction sponsor can create options on the quotient of two variables. In the foreign exchange market, if UI is the Canadian dollar exchange rate per US dollar and Uz is the Japanese yen exchange rate per dollar then U2 / U~ is the cross rate or the Japanese yen per Canadian dollar exchange rate. As another example, if U2 is the price of a stock, U, is the earnings on a stock.
Then U2 / U~ is the price earnings multiple of the stock.
Note that UI and U2 in the examples described above have both been based on similar variables such as both based on weather outcomes. However, there is no requirement that Ul and UZ be closely related: in fact, they can represent underlyings that bear little or no relation to one another. For example UI may represent an underlying based on weather and U2 may be an underlying based on a foreign exchange rate.
- 2~2 -Replicating a Path Dependent Option An example embodiment in two-dimensions can offer customers the ability to trade path dependent options. For example, consider a call option with an out-of the-money knock out.
Namely, the option pays out if the minimum of the exchange rate remains above a certain barrier k,, and spot is above the strike kw on expiration.
Let Xt denote the exchange rate of a currency per dollar at time t. Let Ut denote the minimum value of the exchange rate over a time period so that U1=Min fX, 05 t 5 T} 10.2.3AA
where T denotes the expiration of the option. Let U2 denote XT, the exchange rate at time T.
Then the derivatives strategy pays out as follows 0 if U, < k,, or UZ < kw d(U,,UZ)= UZ-k", ifkv<U,andkW5U2 10.2.3AB
Therefore, the replicating digitals are 0 for i =1, 2, ..., v and j =,1, 2, ..., SZ
ay = E[UZ ~ k,.'_~ S U~ < k; & k~_, _< UZ < k j ] - kW 10.2.3AC
fori=v+l,v+2,...,S,andj=1,2,...,SZ
For a sell of this option strategy, e-E[UZ ~k,.', __<U, <k,' &k~-, SUZ <k~]
a;~ = for i =1, 2, ..., v and j =1, 2, ..., SZ 10.2.3AD
0 fori=v+l,v+2,...,5, and j=1,2,...,52 It is worth noting that the replicating digitals depend on the quantity - 2~3 -E[UZ (k,.'-, __<U, <k.' &k~-, SUZ <k1) 10.2.3AE
which is equal to E[XT ~ k,.'_, <_ Min f X,, 0 S t <_ T ] < k; , k~-, < XT < k~ ) 10.2.3AF
Note that Min {X,, 0 _< t 5 T'~ and XT are in general not independent quantities: for example, they will be positively correlated if the path of the exchange rate follows a Brownian motion. Thus this conditional expectation may require methods that incorporate this correlation to compute this quantity.
Note that this strategy d has unbounded replication P&L. The auction sponsor could offer customers a knock out call spread to allow for strategies with bounded replication P&L.
10.2.4 Replicating Derivatives Strategies Based on Three or More Variables Using the general formulas in section 10.1 such as equation 10.1I, an auction sponsor could replicate other types of derivatives strategies. To trade out of the money knockout options and in the money knockout options, one could set Ul to be the minimum over a time period, U2 to be a maximum over a time period, and U3 to represent the closing value over the time period.
Section 10.3 Estimating the Distribution of the Underlying U
Sections 10.1 and 10.2 describe how to replicate derivatives strategies using digital options. This replication technique depends on certain aspects of the distribution of the underlying U. For example, the replicating digitals and the replication variance for vanilla options depend upon E[U ~ ks_, <_ U < k, ) and Yar[U ~ ks_, S U < kf ) . This section shows how different example embodiments can be used to compute these conditional moments and, more generally, the distribution of U. The formulations in this Section 10.3, can be used and apply equally to determine the conditional moments and the distributions of U for embodiments in which the -26~-replicating basis is the vanilla replicating basis (using replicating vanillas alone or together with replicating digitals) discussed in Section 11.2 et seq., as opposed to being the digital replicating basis (using replicating digitals alone) discussed in this Section 10 and in Section 11.1.
Techniques for estimating the distribution of U can be broadly divided into global approaches and local approaches. In a global approach, a single parametric distribution is fitted or hypothesized for the distribution of the underlying. An example of a global approach would be to use a normal distribution or log-normal distribution to model the underlying. In contrast, in a local approach seveiral distributions may be combined together to fit the underlying. For instance, a local approach may use a different distribution for each state in the sample space.
Independent of whether the auction sponsor uses a global or local approach, the auction sponsor has to choose whether or not to estimate the replicating digitals based on the auction prices.
Allowing the replicating digitals to depend on the auction prices may help keep the conditional mean of the replication P&L equal to zero (where the mean is conditioned on the auction prices), as these replicating digitals will be based on the market determined distribution for U. However, this dependence on auction prices adds iterations to the calculation engine as follows: when the equilibrium prices change due to say a new order, then the replication amounts for each order will change, which will then change the equilibrium prices, which will again change the ' replication amounts; and so on. This process will slow down the calculation of equilibrium prices. On the other hand, if the replicating digitals are constant through the auction and do not depend on the auction prices, then convergence techniques will not require this extra iteration but the replication P&L may not have a conditional mean equal to zero, given the auction prices.
If the auction sponsor wants to offer customers fixed priced options as discussed in section 10.2.2, then the auction sponsor will have to adopt the more computationally intensive technique to compute the equilibrium, since the set of replicating digitals depend upon the auction prices for these options.
This section begins with a discussion of the global approach in section 10.3.1 followed by a discussion of the local approach in 10.3.2.

10.3.1 The Global Approach This section discusses how the auction sponsor can use the global approach for estimating the distribution of U. First, this section describes how the auction sponsor selects a distribution for S the underlying. Second, this section describes how the auction sponsor estimates the parameters of that distribution. Then, this section shows how the auction sponsor can compute the replicating digitals after the parameters of the distribution are estimated.
This section concludes with an illustrative example.
i0 Classes of Distributions for the Underlying The auction sponsor may assume that the underlying follows a log-normal distribution, a distribution that is used frequently when the underlying is the price of a financial asset or for other variables that can only take on positive values. The log-normal model is used, for example, 1 S in the Black-Scholes pricing formula. The auction sponsor may model the underlying to be normally distributed, a distribution that has been shown to approximate many variables. In addition if the underlying is the continuously compounded return on an asset, then the return will be normally distributed if the price of the asset is log-normally distributed.
20 The auction sponsor may choose a distribution that matches specific characteristics of the distribution of the underlying. If the underlying has fatter tails than the normal distribution, then the auction sponsor may model the underlying as t distributed If the underlying has positive skewness, then the auction sponsor might model the underlying as gamma distributed. If the underlying has time-varying volatility, then the auction sponsor may model the underlying as a 25 GARCHprocess.
In addition to the continuous distributions described above, the auction sponsor may model the underlying using a discrete distribution, since many underlyings may in fact take on only a discrete set of values. For example, US CPI is reported to the nearest tenth and heating degree 30 days are typically reported to the nearest degree, so both of these are discrete random variables.
- 2~6 To handle discreteness, the auction sponsor may model U as a discrete random variable such as a multinomial random variable. In other example embodiments, the auction sponsor may choose to discretize a continuous random variable. For notation, let p denote the level of precision to which that the underlying U is reported. For example, p equals 0.1 if the underlying U is US CPI
and p equals 1 if the underlying U is heating degree days. To model U as a discretized random variable let V denote a continuous distributed random variable and let xint V +0.5 10.3.1A
U=R~y~P)=P
P
where "int" represents the greatest integer function. U is discreHzed through the function R
applied to the continuous random variable V.
Selecting the Appropriate Distribution The auction sponsor may select the distribution using a variety of techniques.
First, the choice of the distribution may be dictated by financial theory. For example, as in the Black-Scholes formula, the log-normal distribution is often used when U denotes the price of a financial instrument. Because of this, the normal distribution is often used when U
denotes the return on the financial instrument.
If historical data on the underlying is available, the auction sponsor can perform specifccation tests to determine a distribution that fits the historical data. For example, the auction sponsor may use historical data to compute excess kurtosis to test whether the normal distribution fits as well as the t distribution for U. As another example, the auction sponsor may use historical data to test for GARCH effects to see if a GARCH model would best fit the data. If the underlying is a discretized version of a continuous distribution, then the specification tests may specifically incorporate this information.
Estimating the Parameters of the Distribution The auction sponsor may estimate the parameters of the distribution using a variety of approaches.
If historical data is available on the underlying, then the auction sponsor can estimate the parameters of the distribution using techniques such as moment matching and maximum likelihood. If the variable is discrete, then this discreteness may be modeled explicitly using maximum likelihood.
If options are traded on the underlying, then the auction sponsor can use these option prices to estimate the distribution of the underlying. A large body of academic literature uses the prices on options to estimate the distribution of the underlying. In these methods the implied volatility is expressed as a function of the option's strike price and then numerical derivatives are used to determine the distribution of the underlying. For example, if the 25 delta calls have a higher implied volatility than the 75 delta calls, then this method will likely imply a negative skewness 1 S in the distribution of the underlying.
If market economists or analysts forecast the underlying, the auction sponsor can use these forecasts to help determine the mean and standard deviation of the underlying.
For example, when U represents an upcoming economic data release in the US such as nonfarm payrolls, between 20 and 60 economists will often forecast the release. The mean and standard-deviation of these forecasts for instance may provide accurate estimates of the mean and standard deviation of~the.underlying. As another example, many equity analysts forecast the earnings for US large companies so if the underlying is the quarterly earnings of a large company, analyst forecasts can be .used to estimate the parameters of the distribution.
In addition, an. auction sponsor may determine parameters of the distribution based on the auction's implied distribution. In this case, an example embodiment may set the parameters of the distribution such that the implied probabilities of each state based on the distribution is close to or equal to the implied probabilities based on the auction's distribution.
Computing Replication Quantities from the Distribution -26~-Once the auction sponsor has determined the distribution and the parameters of the distribution, the auction sponsor can then compute the quantities for the digital replication. For example, the quantity of replicating digitals for many option strategies such as vanilla options depend on E[U ~ ks_, <_ U < ks ] and the replication variance for these options depend upon S Yar[U ~ kJ-, <_ U < kJ ] . This section shows how to evaluate these quantities.
Consider the case where U is normally distributed with a mean p and standard deviation a. Since U is a continuous random variable, the rounding parameter p equals 0. Let the option strikes be denoted as 1~ for s =1, 2, ..., S 1. Appendix l OC shows that for s = 2, 3, .
. ., S 1 ~ (kJ-~ - f~)Z (k= - ~)2 exp - - exp -2~. 2~2 2~2 E[U)ky_, _<U<k,]_~r+ k - k -~ 10.3.1B
where "exp" denotes the exponential function or raising the argument to the power of e.
In this case; the variance of replication P&L will depend upon Yar[U ~ ks_1 S
U < ks J , which is 1 S equal to Yar[U~k,_, <U<ks]=E[UZ ~ks_, <U<k,]-(E[U~ks-, SU<k~))2 k, !u Z. f~,>a (u)du k'-' -(E[U~ks_, SU<ks])2 10.3.1C
Pr[kj_, S U< ks where f~>a denotes the normal density function with mean p and standard deviation a. To evaluate this expression, the integral can be computed using for example numerical techniques.
Next consider the case where U is a discretized normal. That is, let Y be normally distributed with a mean p and standard deviation a and let Ube a function of Yas follows -26~-U = R(Y, p) 10.3.1 D
where R is defined in equation 10.3.1 A. In this case, all outcomes of U are divisible by p.
Assume that each strike ks is exactly equal to a possible outcome of U and then for s = 2, 3, ..., S
E[U ( k,_1 <- U < k, ] = E[R(Y, P) ( ksa S R(Y, P) < ks ]
k -p ~vPr[v- p/2 S V < v+ p/2]
,~.-k,_, Pr[ks_~ -pl25Y<ks-pl2]
k-~vPr[v-p/2-<V<v+p/2J
- ks _~ _ (P/2) ks_~ -f~-(Pl2) Q - ~ ~ a-k~ v-~+(Pl2) v-f~-(Pl2) _ "~Gk~~-, ~ a.
ks -,u-(pl2) _ ks_1-,u-(pl2) 10.3.1E
O' where the summation variable v increases in increments of p.
Recall that the replication variance depends on Yar[U ~ ks_, <- U < ks ] , which is equal to Yar[U~ks_, <U<k~]=E[UZ ~ks_; 5U<ks]-(E[U~kJ-, __<U<kf])2 k -P
~vzPr[v-p/25Y<v+p/2]
_ ~.=k,_.
Pr[ks-,-pl2<V<ks-pl2]
l - (E[U ~ k,_, <_ U < kf ])2 k~ y2 NCv-f~+(Pl2)1-NCv-p-(Pl2) ,._,~ _ 6 Pr[ks-,-pl2<_Y<k,-pl2]
-(E[U ~ k~_, < U < ks])z 10.3.1F
S Ezample for Computing the Distribution and Replicating Digitals Consider the following example to compute the replicating digitals for an auction using the global approach. Assume that the auction sponsor runs an auction for the change in US nonfarm payrolls for October 2001 as released on November 2, 2001. This example will show how economist forecasts can be used to create, the replicating digitals. The underlying U is measured in the change in the thousands of number of employed so an underlying value of 100 means a payroll change of 100,000 people. The payrolls are rounded to the nearest thousand: since the underlying is in thousands, then p=1.
Table 10.3.1-1 shows forecasts from 55 economists surveyed by Bloomberg for this economic release. These forecasts have a mean of -299.05 thousand people with a standard deviation of 70.04 thousand people.

Table 10.3.1-1: Economist forecasts for October 2001 change in US nonfarm payrolls in thousands of people.

-360 . -325 -300 -275 -150 If the auction sponsor assumes that U is a discretized version of the normal, then the likelihood function is Likelihood Function = ~ NC'f' ~ + (p ~ 2) f ' -'u - (P ~ 2) 10.3.1 G
a where denotes the forecast from the t-th economist. The maximum likelihood estimators give a mean of -299.06 and a standard deviation of 69.40. Note that the maximum likelihood estimates are quite close to the sample mean and standard deviation, suggesting that the rounding parameter p is a small factor in the maximum likelihood estimation.
For this auction, the strikes are set to be X25, -375, -325, -275; -225 and -175. Table 10.3.1-2 shows the values of Pr[kJ-1 5 U < ks ] , E[U ~ ks_, 5 U < ks ] , and Yar[U ( ks-~ <_ U < ks ] based on the model that the outcome is a discretized version of the normal with mean -299.06 with a standard deviation of 69.40 and rounding to the nearest integer (p=1). This model is referred to as the discretized normal model.

Table 10.3.1-Z: The probabilities, the conditional mean, and the conditional variance for the discredzed normal model.
State I State 2 State 3 State 4 State 5 State 6 State 7 U<-425 -425 <= U<-375 -375 <= U< 325 -325 <= U < -275 -275 <= U < -225 -225 <=
U< -175 -175 <= U
Probability of State 0.0342 0.1011 0.2162 0.2813 0.2225 0.1071 0.0375 Conditional Expectation:
E[IJ~state s]- X52.01 -396.26 -348.32 -300.44 -252.55 -204.62 -147.75 Conditional Variance:
Var[U~state s] 609.13 194.14 201.88 204.67 202.18 194.70 618.05 Based on this model one can compute the replicating digitals for different derivatives strategies.
Table 10.3.1-3 shows these replicating digitals, the prices of the strategies, and the variance of replication P&L.
Table 10.3.1-3: The replicating tiigitals, prices, and variances of differtrlt strategies based on the global normal model.
StateStateStateStateStateStateStatePrice Replication 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 of <= <= <= <= <=
U U U U U

Derivative StrategyU <-375< < < < -175 StrategyVariance <-425 -325 -275 -225 -175 <=
U

Buy a digital 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 L00 1.00 0.64840 call swck at-325 Buy a digital 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.63290 put struck at-275 Buy a range binary with strikes of -375 and 225 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 0.72000 Buy a vanilla 0.00 0.00 0.00 24.5672.45120.38177.2542.5715146.60 call struck at-325 Buy.a vanilla 177.01121.2673.3225.440.00 0.00 0.00 41.3320141.70 put struck at Buy a call spread stn'kes at -375 and-225 0.00 0.00 26.6874.56122.45150.00150.0075.6798146.22 Buy a put spread stn'kes at -375 and -225 150.00150.00123.3275.4427.550.00 0.00 74.3202146.22 1 S 10.3.2 Local Approach In addition to the global approach described above, an auction sponsor can apply a local approach where the underlying is modeled with a large number of parameters. In particular, the local approach can be set up to have more parameters than states, whereas the global approach typically only has one or two parameters. The local approach allows the auction sponsor to fit the distribution of Uwith great flexibility.
The Intrastate Uniform Model Assume that the distribution of U is discrete and that given that U is between ks_~ and ks, U is equally likely to be any of the possible outcomes within that state. In other words, if U is between ks_1 and ks, then U takes on the values ks-1, ks_1+p, ks_i+2p, ..., ks P 10.3.2A
and Pr[U = kJ_, ] = Pr[U = ks-, + p] _ ... = Pr[U = kJ - p] 10.3.2B
This intrastate uniform model can be used to compute the replicating digitals and the variance of the replicating digitals.
The conditional mean and the conditional variance for the intrastate uniform model ale for s = 2, 3, ..., S 1 E[U~k,_, <U<k,]=k=-' ~° '° 10.3.2C
Yar[U ~ k,-, < U< ks ] _ ~k' kJ-' P12ka ks ' + P) 10.3.2D
Note that these quantities are parameter free, even though the distribution of U and the variance of C depend on probabilities of each state occurring. The variance in equation 10.3.2D is derived in appendix l OC.

For the intrastate uniform model, the conditional variance of U can be written as for s = 2, 3, ..., Yar[U ~ ks-, <_ U< k~ ] _ (ks kl~ P -10.3.2E
Thus, the variance is an increasing function of the distance between the strikes. In an example embodiment, the auction sponsor can decrease the variance of replication P&L, all other things being equal, by decreasing the distance between the strikes. This result holds for the intrastate uniform model, but will hold for other example embodiments as well.
It is worth considering three special cases for this model. In the case where p=(7~-ks_~)l2, there are two possible outcomes in state s so U is binomially distributed with the two values ks_1 and ks_ 1+p = I~_I+(ks ks_1)l2=(ks+ks_1)l2. In this case, the conditional mean and the conditional variance isfors=2,3,...,51 E[U ~ k,_, _< U< ks ] = k$-' +~ J P _ k3-' + (k,-2+ 2 p) - p - ks-~ + ~
10.3.2F
Yar[U ~ k,_, S U< k$ ] _ (k' k$-' P)(ks - ksa + P) _ (2P - P)(2P + P) Pz - 4 10.3.26 In the special case of p=ks ks_I, the underlying only takes on the value ks_1 in the range of state s.
Therefore, the conditional mean and the conditional variance is for s = 2, 3, ..., S 1 E[U ~ ks-, < U< ks ] = ks_, 10.3.2H
- 27~ -Yar[U~k,-, <_U<k,]=0 10.3.2I
The case of p=0 implies that U is continuous, and in this case, for s = 2, 3, ..., S 1 E[U ~ ks-, <_ U< kf J = kf-'2 ks 10.3.2J
_ z Yar[U ~ ks-, _< U< kJ ] _ (ks 12s ' ) 10.3.2K
In contrast to the intrastate uniform model, another example embodiments might assume that the probability mass function of U is non-negative and takes the form Pr[U = a ~ ks-, <_ U< kJ ] = p(rf + ~su) 10.3.2L
This restriction allows the probability mass function to have a non-zero slope intrastate, as opposed to the intrastate uniform model where the probability mass function has a slope of zero intrastate. An example embodiment might estimate the parameters rs and ~S of this model such that these parameters minimize (Pr,..J,mt [kJ-z < U< k,-, ] - P.~a ~ + ~Prr,.m, [ks < U< ks+~ ] - P~+i ~
10.3.2M
vi~here Prrj,~s [ks-z _< U< ks-, ] denotes the probability of state s-1 occurring based on rs and ~S, Pr,.~,mf [k$ S U< k3+, ] denotes the probability of state s+1 occurring based on rs and ~S, and ps_I
andp~l denote the probability that the state's s-1 and s+1 occur based on the auction pricing.
Example Consider the change in US nonfarm payrolls auction for October 2001 with the strikes -425, -375, -325, -275, -225 and -175. In addition to the assumptions above for the intrastate uniform model, assume that - 27~ -E[U ~ U < -425] _ -450.50 10.3.2N
E[U ( -175 5 U] _ -150.50 10.3.20 Table 10.3.2-1 shows Pr[ks-, <_ U < kJ ], E[U ~ ks-, <_ U < k, ], and Tsar[U ~
ks_, _< U < ks ] based on this intrastate uniform mode]. The probabilities of each state occurring are equal to those from table 10.3.1-2 by assumption. Note that the conditional expectations and the conditional variance for the intrastate uniform model are different than those quantities for the discretized norms]
iriodel in table 10.3.1-2.
Table 10.3.2-1: The probabilities, the conditional mean, and the conditional variance for the intrastate uniform model.
State State State State State State State <= <= <= <= <=
U U U U U

U <-425<.375 < -325 < -275< -225< -175 -175 <=
U

Probability 0.03420.10110.2162 0.28130.22250.1071 0.0375 of State Conditional Expectation:

E[Zl~state s] -450.50-400.50-350.50-300.50-250.50-200.50-150.50 Conditional Variance:

Var[Il~state 208.25208.25208.25 208.25208.25208.25 208.25 s]

Table 10.3.2-2 shows the replicating digitals, the prices, and the variance based on the intrastate uniform model. Note that the replicating digitals for the discretized normal mode] and intrastate uniform mode] are the same for the digital call, the digits] put, and the range binary. Note that these replicating values are different for all other options.

Table 10.3.2-2: The replicating digitals, price of strategy, and variance of different strategies based on the intrastate uniform model.
StateState State State State State StatePriceReplication 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 of <= <= <= <= <=
U<- U< U< U< U<

Derivative StrategyU<-425375 -325 -275 -225 -175 -175 StrategyVariance <=
U

Buy a digital call struck at 325 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 L00 1.00 1.00 0.64840 Buy a digital put struck at-275 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.63290 Buy a range binary with strikes of-375 0.00 0.00 1.00 L00 1.00 0.00 0.00 0.72000 and -225 Buy a vanilla call struck at-325 0.00 0.00 0.00 24.50 ?4.50 124.50 174.5043.3494135.03 Buy a vanilla put shuck at 275 175.50125.5075.50 25.50 0.00 0.00 0.00 42.1964131.79 Buy a call spread strikes at -375 and 0.00 0.00 24.50 74.50 124.50150.00 150.0075.6493149.95 Buy a put spread stn'kes at -375 and 150.00150.00125.50 75.50 25.50 0.00 0.00 74.3507149.95 Figures 27A, 27B, and 27C show the functions d and C for a vanilla call option with a strike of -325 computed using the intrastate uniform model. Figures 28A, 28B, and 28C
show the functions d and C for a call spread with strikes of -375 and -225 also using the intrastate uniform model.
10.4 Replication P&L for a Set of Orders Previous sections showed how to compute the replication P&L for a single order for a specific derivatives strategy. This section shows how to compute the replication P&L on a set of orders or an entire auction.
10.4.1 Replication 'P&L in the General Case As before, assume U takes on values in S2, where S2 has a countable number of elements.
Assume that the sample space S2 is divided into S disjoint and non-empty subsets 521, 522, ..., S2s.
Assume that Pr[U--u] is the probability that outcome a occurs. Therefore, p, _ ~Pr[U = u) for s=1, 2, ..., S 10.4.1A
urS2~
where ps denotes the probability that state s occurs as defined in equation 10.1 C.
S Let Jdenote the number of filled customer orders and let these orders be indexed by the variable j, j =1, ..., J. Let d~ denote the payout function for the strategy for order j. For example if the jth order is a call spread with strikes k,, and kw, then 0 for U < kv dl(U)= U-k,, for k,,<-U<kw 10.4.1B
kW - k,, for kW < U
Denote the filled notional payout amount for order j as x~. It is worth noting that the derivations in sections 10.1, 10.2, and 10.3 implicitly assumed a notional payout value of 1 unit for each order. Let x denote the vector of length J, whose jth element is xf.
Let a~,s denote the replicating digital for state s for order j. For instance, if the jth order is a call spread then the replicating digitals are Ofors=1,2,...,v a~,,= E[U~ks-,-_<U<k,)-kvfors=v+1,v+2,...,w 10.4.1C
kw - ky for s = w+ 1, w + 2, ..., S
Further let a J = min E[d~ (U) ~ U E S2 J ) 10.4.1 D
.,=~,z,....s Let C denote the replication P&L for this set of orders (in sections 10.1, 10.2, and 10.3, C
previously denoted the replication P&L for a single order). The replication P&L for this set of orders if the orders are buys of strategies d~ is J
C=~x~[a~~ -d~(U)+el] 10.4.1E
Iri this case, one can compute the expected replication P&L and the variance of replication P&L
.from the auction as follows E[C] _ ~Pr[U = a]C(u) 10.4.1F
urS2 Yar[C] _ (~ Pr[U = a]C(u)2 ) - (E[C])2 10.4.1 G
ud~
(Note that C depends on the outcome a of Uand equation 10.4.1F and equation 10.4.16 makes that explicit by writing C(u)). Using formula 10.4.1E one can compute the infimum replication P&L for the set of buy orders by computing the replication P&L over all possible values a of U.
In the event that the sample space S2 takes on an uncountable number of values, formulas 10.4.1F
and 10.4.1 G will require modification.
10.4.2 Replication P&L for Special Cases Consider the following types of derivative strategies:
Digital calls, digital puts, and range binaries ~ Vanilla calls and vanilla puts ~ Call spreads and put spreads ~ Straddles and collared straddles ~ Forwards and collared forwards These derivative strategies all have the property that their payout fimctions d can be written as piece wise linear functions. The section below derives formulas for the replication variance for auctions with these derivative strategies.
Let D be a matrix with J rows and S columns. Define the element in the jth row and sth column D~,$ as follows - 2~0 -1 if the replication risk for order j is an increasing function of U over state s D~,, = 0 if the replication risk for order j over state s is zero 10.4.2A
-1 if the replication risk for order j is an decreasing function of U over state s Because digital calls, digital puts, and range binaries have no replication P&L, then if order j is either a buy or sell of one of these instruments then D~,, =Ofor s=1,2,...,5 10.4.2B
If order j is a buy of a call spread with strikes k" and k", (or a sell of a put spread with strikes kv and k~,,), then 0 fors=1,2,...,v D~,s= 1 fors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.4.2C
0 fors=w+l,w+2,...,S
Similarly if order j is a sell of a call spread with strikes of k" and kW (or a buy of a put spread with 1 S strikes kV and k",) then 0 for s =1, 2, ..., v D~,,= -1 fors=v+l,v+2,...,w 10.4.2D
0 fors=w+l,w+2,...,5 Next, it is worth considering two special cases to compute the variance of the replication P&L.
Case I: Yar[UJ<oo , 1n this case, one can compute the variance of replication P&L for an auction with the following strategies:
~ Digital calls, digital puts, and range binaries ~ Vanilla calls and vanilla puts -2~ll -~ Call spreads and put spreads ~ Straddles and collared straddles ~ Forwards and collared forwards Let Une,~, be a vector of length S defined such that the sth element of Une,t, is T[U E S2s ](E[U ~ U E S2, ] - U) 10.4.2E
for s =1, 2, ..., S. Note, of course, that Un~, does not depend on order j.
The replication P&L
from an auction with these orders is C=xT xD x U"e", 10.4.2F
Then, l S Yar[C] = Yar[xT x D x U"e".) = xT x D x Yar[ Un~,,J x DT x x 10.4.26 Because of the definition of Une", and the fact that (E[U ~ ks_~ S U < ks ] -U) is mean 0, then Yar[U"e,s,] is a diagonal matrix where the element in the sth diagonal position is p,Yar[U~ks_, SU<ksJ.
Case II: Yar[U]=oo. In this case, the equations from Case I can be modified to compute the variance of replication P&L for auctions with the following instruments, which all have finite replication P&L (see table 10.2.2-1):
~ Digital calls, digital puts, and range binaries ~ Call spreads and put spreads ~ Collared straddles ~ Collared forwards Let Une", be a vector of length S defined such that the sth element of U"e", is - 2~2 -I[U E S2S ](E[U ( U E S2s ] - U) 10.4.2H
for s = 2, ..., S 1 and let the first element and Sth element equal 0. The replication P&L from an auction with these orders is C = xT x D x Une", 10.4.2I
Then, Yar[C] = Yar[xT x D x U"eW] 10.4.2) =xTxDx Yar[U"eW] xDTxx 10.4.2K
Because of the definition of U"eW and the fact that (E[U ~ ks_, < U < ks ] -U) is mean 0, then Yar[U"~,,,,] is a diagonal matrix where the element in the sth diagonal position is psYar[U ~ ks_1 5 U < ks ] for s = 2, 3, ..., S -l and zero in element 1 and S.
Example To illustrate Case II, consider the example from section 10.3 with S=7 states with strikes -425, -375, -325, -275, -225 and -175. Table 10.4.2-1 shows the D's for a buy of a call spread with strikes -375 and -225 and a buy of a put spread with strikes -425 and -275, both with filled notional amounts of 1. For this example, assume that the conditional variance of each state is modeled according to the intrastate uniform model of section 10.3.2 as shown in table 10.3.2-1.
Table 10.4.2-1 shows that the variance of replication P&L for the call spread and put spread is 149.95 and 124.66 respectively. For J--2, these two orders combined together in an auction have a replication variance of 67.40. Because of the netting in the D's from these orders in states 3 and 4, the replication variance for these combined orders is less than the sum of the replication variance of each order. (In fact, the replication variance for these combined orders is less than the replication variance of each order individually, because the orders netted together have - 2~3 -replication risk on states with lower probabilities.) This netting phenomenon is likely to be a feature of many different sets of orders, keeping replication P&L growing less than linearly in J, the number of orders filled.
S Table '10.4.2-1: The Matrix D and Replication P&L for Multiple Orders State State State State State State 6 State -425 -375 -325 -275 -225 <= U Replication <-- <= <= <=
U U U U

Derivative StrategyU <-0256375 < -325< -275< -225 < -175 -175 Variance <= U

Buy a call spread strikes at -375 and 225 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 149.95 Buy a.put spread strikes at -425 and 275 0 -1 -1 -1 0 0 0 124.66 Appendix 10A: Notation Used in Section 10 as: a scalar representing the replicating digital for strategy d for s =1, 2, ..., S;
a~: a~scalar representing the replicating quantity of digitals for state (i, j) for i=1, 2, ..., S~ and j=l, 2, ..., S2 when U is two-dimensional;
a~,s: a scalar representing the replicating digital for order j in state s for j=1, 2, ..., .I and s= l, 2, ..., S;
C: a one-dimensional random variable representing the replication P&L to the auction sponsor;
d: a function representing the payout on a derivatives strategy based on the underlying U, also d(U);
d~: a function representing the payout on a derivatives strategy for order j;
D: a matrix with Jrows and S columns containing 1's, 0's, and -1's;
e: a scalar representing the minimum conditional expected value of d(U) across states s for s=l, 2, ..., S;
a : a scalar representing the maximum conditional expected value of d(U) across states s for s=1, 2, ..., S;
e! : a scalar representing the minimum conditional expected value of d~{U) for order j across states s for s=1, 2, ..., S;
E: the expectation operator;
Exp: the exponential function raising the argument to the power of e;
2g5 -fN,a : the density of a normally distribution random variable with mean p. and standard deviation 6;
1 the indicator function;
' Inf-. the infimum function;
J a scalar representing the number of customer orders in an auction;
Ire, k1, ..., ks: scalar quantities representing strikes for the case when Uis one-dimensional;
ko, k; , ki, k3 , ..., ks, : scalar quantities representing strikes for UI for the case when U is two-dimensional;
ko , k; , k2 , k; , ..., k ; : scalar quantities representing strikes for U2 for the case when U is two-dimensional;
k=: a scalar representing the target strike for an option order;
N: the cumulative distribution function for the standard normal;
ps: a scalar representing the probability that state s or S2S has occurred for s = 1, 2, ..., S;
p~: a scalar representing the target price for an option order;
p;~ : a scalar representing the probability that state (i, j) has occurred for i=1, 2, ..., S~ and j=1, 2, ..., S2 when U is two-dimensional;
Pr: the probability operator;
R: the rounding function, which discretizes a continuous distribution;
-2~6-s: a scalar used to index across the states;
S: a scalar representing the number of states;
Sl : a scalar representing the number of states for UI when U is two-dimensional;
Sz: a scalar representing the number of states for Uz when U is two-dimensional;
U a random variable representing the underlying;
u: a possible outcome of U from the sample space S2 Ul and Uz: one-dimensional random variables representing the first and second elements of U
1 S when U is two-dimensional;
U"e,4,: a random vector of length S where the sth element is I[U E S2S )(E[U ( U E S2J ] - U) for s=
1,2,...,5;
Yar: the variance operator;
x: awector of length J of filled notional amounts x~;
x~: a scalar representing the filled notional amount of orderj, j =1, 2, ..., J;
S2: a set of points representing the sample space of U;
52,, S2z, ..., S2s: subsets of the sample space S2;
p: a scalar representing the rounding parameter;
- Zg7 -Appendix 10B: The General Replication Theorem This appendix derives the formulas for the replicating digitals, the infimum replication P&L, and the variance of replication P&L for buys and sells of derivatives strategies.
S
As a review of notation from section 10. l, recall that U denotes the underlying. Let S2 denote the sample space of U and let 521, 522, ..., S2s represent the different sets of outcomes of U. Let d represent the derivatives strategy and define to a = min E[d (U) f U E S2s ] l OB.A
s=1,2,...,5 e ---_ max E[d (U) ~ U E S2, ) l OB.B
s=1,2,...,5 The derivation below requires d to satisfy the following restriction OSe< a<oo lOB.C
Let (al, a2, ::., as_i, as) represent the positions in the replicating digitals, and let C denote the replication P&L, which is given by the formula s C = ~ 1[U E S2, ][aJ - d (U) + e] l OB.D
s=1 General Replication Theorem. If (a,, a2, ..., as_~, as) are selected to minimize Yar[C] subject to E[C] = 0 , then for a buy of d as = E[d (U) ~ U E S2s ]- a for s =1, 2, . .., S l OB.E
where d satisfies condition l OB.C. The infimum replication P&L for a buy of d is inf C = min ~ inf (E[d (U) ~ U E S2s J - d(U))J l OB.F
s=1,2,...,S Uefl, Further, for a sale of the derivatives strategy d, the replicating digitals are given by the formula S as = e-E~d (U) ~ U E S2f ~ for s =1, 2, ..., 5 lOB.G
The infimum replication P&L for a sell of d is given by inf C = min ~ inf (d (U) - E[d (U) ( U E S2s )) l OB.II
s=1,2,...,5 Us(1 The variance of replication P&L for both buys and sells of d is S
Yar[C] _ ~ pfYar[d (U) ~ U E S2, ] l OB.I
s=1 1 S Proof. First, begin with the derivation of the result for a buy of d. In this case Yar[C] -- E[(C - E[C])2 J
= E[C2 ] 1 OB.J
where the first equality is the definition of variance and the second equality follows from the constraint E[C)=0. Since s C = ~ I[U E S2s ] [as - d (U) + e] l OB.K
s=1 Therefore, s s Cz =~~I[U E S2J]I[U E S2r](aJ -d(U)+~(ar -d(U)+e) r=I :=I
s ~1[U E SZJ]z(aJ -d(U)+e)z J=I
S S
+ ~ ~l[U E S2J]I[U E S2r](aJ -d(U)+e)(ar -d(U)+e) 10B.L
r=t,r*J J=I
Note that in the second term on the RHS of equation IOB.L, the cross product terms contain the quantity I[U E S2JJI[U E SZr] for t $ s lOB.M
Since S2S and SZt are mutually exclusive for t ~ s, then 1[U E S2J ]I[U E S2r]=0 for t ~ s lOB.N
1 S Therefore, s Cz =~I[U E S2J]z(aJ -d(U)+e)z J=I
_ ~I[U E ~J](aJ -d(U)+~z 10B.0 s=1 where the last equation follows from the fact that squaring an indicator function leaves it unchanged, i.e. Iz--I. Therefore, taking expectations of both sides of equation l OB.O gives s Yar[C]=~E[I[U E S2J](aJ -d(U)+e)z] lOB.P
J=t - 2~0 -Taking the derivative with respect to as for s = 1, 2, ..., S and setting to zero gives the first order condition E[I[U E S2s ](as - d (U) + e)] = 0 for s =1, 2, . .., S l OB.Q
S
or E[I [U E S2S ]as ] - E[I[U E S2s ]d (U)] + E[I[U E S2s L] = 0 for s = l, 2, ..., S l OB.R
which implies that PJas - P,E[d (U) ~ U E S2s ] + p$ a = 0 for s =1, 2, . .., S l OB.S
Factoring out ps and solving for aS implies that a, = E~d (U) ~ U E SZs ~- a for s = l, 2, .. ., S l OB.T
Next, one needs to check that E[C]=0 because that assumption was used in the derivation above.
Now, s C=~I[UES2s][a,-d(U)+e] lOB.U
s=~
Substituting equation l OB.T for aS into the equation l OB.U gives s C = ~ I[U E S2s ] (E[d (U) ~ U E S2, ] - d (U)) 1 OB. V
s=1 Taking the expectations of both sides - 2~~ -s E(C) = E ~ 1[U~S2f ][E[d (U) I Ud2s ] - d (U)]
s=I
s _ ~ E [ILU~S2s ] [E[d (v) I U~s l - d(U)ll s=1 S
s = ~ (psE[d(U) I U E ~s ] - PsE[d (U) I v E ~, l) s=i = 0 lOB.W
To compute the variance of the replication P&L, recall equation l OB.P
s Yar[C] _ ~ E[I[U E SZs ] [as - d (U) + _e]2 ] 1 OB.X
S=I
OW, E[I[U E S2J ] [as - d (U) + a]Z ) = psE[(as - d (U) + e)2 I U E S2s J l OB.Y
Note that by definition of as in equation l OB.T, E[a, - d (U) + a I U E S2s J = 0 l OB.Z
Therefore, PsE[(as - d (U) + e)2 I U E SZs J = pJYar[as - d (U) + a I U E S2J
= pfYar[d (U) I U E S2, J l OB.AA

where the final equality follows from the .fact that as and a are constants and don't impact the variance. Thus, s Yar[C] _ ~ psYar[d (U) ~ U E S2s ] 1 oB.AB
s=1 Furthermore, the infimum replication P&L can be computed as follows inf C = min ~ inf (E[d (U) ~ U E S2s ] - d (U))J l OB.AC
s=1,2,._,S Uef2 To distinguish replicating digitals for a buy of strategy d and replicating digitals for a sell of strategy d, it is useful to temporarily use as to denote the replicating digitals for a buy of strategy d and a, to denote the replicating digital for a sell of strategy d. Outside of this discussion here, as denotes the replicating digitals for both buys or sells of the derivatives strategy d.
A sell of strategy d can be handled by converting this sell into a complementary buy order such that the combined replicating portfolio pays out the same amount regardless of what state occurs.
In this case, denote the replicating digitals for the complementary buy as as and thus as + as = constant for s =1, 2, ..., S l OB.AD
The minimum such constant satisfying this equation and keeping a, non-negative is e- a .
Therefore, as + as = e- a for s =1, 2, ..., S 1 OB.AE
which implies that ar = e- a - ap for s =1, 2, ..., S 1 OB.~

Since as = E~d (U) ~ U E S2s ~- a for s = l, 2, ..., S l OB.AG
Therefore, as = e- E[d (U) ~ U E S2s ] for s =1, 2, ..., S l OB.AH
The formulas for the variance of replication P&L and the infimum replication P&L for sells of d follow from equation lOB.AH.
-~9~-Appendix 10C: Derivations from Section 10.3 This appendix derives results cited in section 10.3.1 and section 10.3,2.
Derivation of Equation 10.3.1B from Section 10.3.1 This section derives equation 10.3.1B from the global normal model in Section 10.3.1. If U is normally distributed, then, the conditional expectation for s = 2, 3,..., S 1 is given by ks ~ufN.a (u)du E[U ~ k,-, 5 U < ks ] = k'-' lOC.A
Pr~ks_, _< U< ks where f~,a denotes the normal density with mean p and standard deviation a.
Now, Pr~kf-, < U< ks]= NLks ~~-~k'-' 'u~ lOC.B
a where N denotes the cumulative distribution function for the standard normal.
Further, _k,-p kJ ~
jufN,a (u)du = J(,u + az) fo,, (z)dz l OC.C
kj_t ks_~_fs a where Z--(U ~)la. Therefore, ks ~uf~,a (u)du E[U ( k$_, < U < ks ] = k°-' N ks - ~ - N ks-~ - ~
ff 6 - 2~5 -k-Q
j~ + ~,ro.~ cZ~dZ
k._i_li _ a ks /u ka-1 lu ~C ~ ~ - ~C ~ ~
ku_ft _ks_f~
Q a j.ro., cZ~~ ~ jZfo,~ cZ~dZ
kJ_v-f~ ks_~_f~
- Q ,+ a ks -,u - N ks_, yc N ks -,u k,-, -,u ~C~.~ C ~ ~ C6~~C ~ ~
_k,-~
a jZfa,, cZ~dZ
k,_~_~
= fl +
kJ ~ f~~
a Ja _kJ-l~
z. Z Z
p_ o-k._~_~ 2~c ex 2 =lu+ a f~~_NCks ~ f~~
a- o J
_k, -~

exp --2~c 2 - k,_,-,~
-~- a k f~~_NCks ~ f~~
Q

_ (ks-1 ~)z _ _ (ks lu)2 2~ exp 2~z exp 2Q2 =,u + lOC.D
~ks _ fc~ _ ~kJ_~ _,u Equation IOC.D matches equation 10.3.1B and so this concludes the derivation.
Derivation of Equation 10.3.2D from Section 10.3.2 This section derives equation 10.3.2D, the variance for the intrastate uniform model. The derivation for the expected value is straightforward and not presented.
Let the variable ZS be defined as Z = [U ~ ks_, <_ U < k, J - kJ_, l OC.E
J
P
The random variable [ U ~ ks_~ _< U < ks] takes on the values ks_l, ks_1+p, ks_1+2p, ..., ks p - lOC.F
all with equal probability, since U is assumed to be uniformly distributed intrastate. Therefore, ZS takes on the values 0, 1, 2, ..., (ks - ks_, - p)lp l OC.G
all with equal probability. An example of a random variable Xtaking on the values 0, 1, 2, ... , n-1 and n (all outcomes equally probable), described on page 141 in Evans, Hastings, and Peacock, Statistical Distributions (Second Edition, Wiley Interscience, New York), has a vaiiance n(n + 2) Yar(~ = 12 lOC.H
Thus, using this result with n = (ks - ks_1- p)/p implies that Yar[Z, ] _ (ks ks-' P)(ks - ksa - P + 2P) 12 pz _ (ks - k=-, - p)(k, - ks-' + P) 10C.I
l2pz Therefore, Yar[.U ~ ks_1 _< U< ks] = p2Yar[ZS]
- (ks - ks-' - P)(ks - k~-' + P) l OC.J

Equation i OC.J matches equation 10.3.2D and so this concludes the derivation.
1'l. REPLICATING AND PRICING DERIVATIVES STRATEGIES USING VANILLA
OPTIONS
Financial. market participants express market views and construct hedges using a number of contingent claims, such as derivatives strategies, including vanilla derivatives strategies (e.g.
vanilla calls, vanilla puts, vanilla spreads, and vanilla straddles) and digital derivatives strategies (e.g. digital calls, digital puts, and digital ranges). Using the techniques described in section 10, an auction sponsor can use digital options to approximate or replicate these derivatives strategies.
_2~g_ Replicating contingent claims, such as derivatives strategies using digital options exposes the auction sponsor to replication risk, the risk derived from synthesizing derivatives strategies for customers using only digital options. To keep replication risk low, the auction sponsor may only be able to offer customers the ability to trade derivatives strategies with low replication risk, which may include vanilla strategies with strikes that are close together. In fact, customers may demand vanilla strategies with a wider range of strikes, requiring the auction sponsor to take on higher replication risk. To offer the full range of strikes demanded by customers, the auction sponsor may be exposed to a significant amount of replication risk when using digital options to replicate customer orders.
This section shows how an auction sponsor can eliminate replication risk by using vanilla options either alone, or together with digital options, instead of digital options alone, as the replicating claims established in the demand-based auction, to replicate digital and vanilla derivatives strategies in an example embodiment. This approach allows the auction sponsor to offer a wider range of strikes, which may increase customer demand in the auctions and better aggregate liquidity. This increased customer demand and liquidity will likely result in higher fee income for the auction sponsor.
In an example embodiment, this replicating approximation may be a mapping from parameters of, for example, vanilla options to the vanilla replicating basis. This mapping could be an automatic function built into a computer system accepting and processing orders in the demand-based market or auction. The replicating approximation enables auction participants or custoriiers to interface with the demand-based market or auction, side by side with custorriers who trade digital options, notes and swaps, as well as other DBAR-enabled products without exposing the auction sponsor to replication risk. Figure 29 shows this visually. All customer orders, including orders for both digital and vanilla options, are aggregated together into a single pool. This approach can help increase the overall liquidity and risk pricing efficiency of the demand-based auction by increasing the variety and number of participants in the market or auction.
The remainder of section 11 proceeds as follows. Section 11.1 provides a brief review from Section 10, on how an auction sponsor can replicate derivatives strategies using digital replication claims (also referred to as replicating digital options) as the replicating claims for the auction (also referred to as replication claims). Next, section 11.2 shows how an auction sponsor can replicate derivatives strategies using vanilla replication claims (also referred to as replicating vanilla options). Section 11.3 extends the results from section 11.2 to consider more general S cases. Section 11.4 develops the mathematical principles for computing the DBAR equilibrium.
Section 11.5 discusses two examples, and section 11.6 concludes with a discussion of an augmented vanilla replicating basis.
11.1 Replicating Derivatives Strategies Using Digital Options :This section briefly reviews how an auction sponsor can replicate derivatives strategies using digital options (for a more detailed discussion, see section 10). Section 11.1.1 introduces the notation and set-up. Section 11.1.2 discusses the digital replicating claims, also referred to as replicating digitals or replicating digital options. Section 11.1.3 shows how an auction sponsor can replicate digital and vanilla derivatives strategies based on these digital replicating claims:
Section 11.1.4 computes the auction sponsor's replication P&L.
11.1.1 Notation and Set-Up For'sirriplicity, assume that the,underlying U (also referred to as the event or the underlying event) is one-dimensional. As in section 10, let p denote the smallest measurable unit of U, or the level of precision to which the underlying U is reported. For example, p equals 0.1 if the underlying U is US CPI. In certain cases, p may be referred to as the tick size of the underlying.
Assume that the auction sponsor allows customers to trade derivatives strategies with strikes k1, k2, ..., ks_,, corresponding to measurements of the event U that are possible outcomes of U, such .
that k, < k2 < k3 < ... < ks-Z < ks_, 11.1.1A
Assume that the strikes k,, k2, ..., ks i are all multiples of p.
- 30~ -Define Ir.~ as the lower bound of U, i.e. U is the largest value that satisfies Pr[U<ko]=0 11.1.1B
In the event that there is no such finite lco satisfying equation 11.1.1B, let. Jro=-~0. Define ks as the upper bound, i.e. ks is the smallest value such that Pr[U>ks]=0 11.1.1C
In the event that there is no such finite ks satisfying equation 11.1.1 C, set ks=-oo. Here, lro and ks are not strikes that customers can trade, but they will be useful mathematically in representing certain equations below.
For derivatives strategies with a single strike, that strike will typically be denoted by k,, where 1 <_ v < S 1. For deritvatives strategies with two strikes, the lower strike will typically be denoted by kV and the upper strike will typically be denoted by k,~, where 1 <_ v < w <_ S 1.
11.1.2 The Digital Replicating Claims in an example embodiment, the auction sponsor may replicate derivatives strategies using digital options. For example, the auction sponsor may use S such digital options (one more option than he number of strikes) for replication. For notation, let d= denote the payout function, also referred to as the payout profile, on the sth such digital replicating claim for s=1, 2, ..., S. The first digital replicating claim will be the digital put struck at k1 which has a payout function of 1 U<k d' (U) _ ' 11.1.2A
0 k, <_ U
The sth digital replicating claim for s=2, 3, ..., S 1 is a digital range or range binary with strikes of kS_1 and ks, which has a payout function of 0 U < kJ-, d s (U) = 1 ks_, 5 U < ks 11.1.2B
0 k3 S U
The Sth digital replicating claim is a digital call struck at kS_1 with payout function 0 U<k S d S (U) - 1 k < U 11.1.2C
Figure 30 and table 11.1.2 display these digital replication claims. This set of claims is referred to as the digital replicating basis. Here, regardless of the outcome of the underlying, exactly one digital replicating claim expires in-the-money.
Table 11.1.2: The digital replicating claims in a DBAR auction.
Range for Claim Non-Zero Number Pa out e licatin Claim 1 U < k1 Di 'tal ut struck at k1 2 k1 <_ U Di 'tal range with strikes < k2 of k1 and k2 s-1 ks_2 < U Di 'tal ran a with strikes < ks_1 of ks_Z and ks_I

s ks_1 < U Digital range with strikes < ks of ks_~ and ks s+1 ks < U < Di 'tal ran a with strikes k,~l of ks and ks+i S 1 ks 2 < U Di 'tal ran a with strikes < kit of ks 2 and ks 1 S k~l <_ U Di 'tal call struck at ks_i 11.1.3 Replicating Derivatives Strategies with Digital Replication Claims Let d denote the payout fimction or payout profile for a derivatives strategy which is European style, i.e. its payout is based solely on the value of the underlying on expiration. Additionally, "derivatives strategy d" in this specification refers to the payout fi.~nction or payout profile of the derivatives strategy, since a derivatives strategy is often identified by its payout fimction. Let as denote the amount or number of the sth digital replicating claim, also referred to as the replication weight for this derivatives strategy d. 'lf'he number or amount of each reg~licatnng claim is determined as a function of the payout profile or payout function d of the derivatives strategy, and the full set of all the replicating claims that replicate or approximate the derivatives strategy can be referred to. as the replication set for the derivatives strategy. In an example embodiment, the replicating weights for a buy of this derivatives strategy d are as = E[d (U) 'k,-, <_ U < kJ ) s =1, 2, ..., S 11.1.3A
Here, the amount of the sth digital claim is the conditional expected value of the payout of the derivatives strategy d, given that the underlying Uis greater than or equal to kS_1 and strictly less than ks. To compute this conditional expected value, the auction sponsor might assume for piecewise linear:functions d that ~d (U) I ks-~ ~ U < k$ ] = d ks-' + ks P
11.1.3B

Section 10.3.2 refers to equation 11.1.3B as the intrastate uniform model.
As now shown, the auction sponsor can use equations 11.1.3A and 11.1.3B to compute the digital replicating weights (al, a2, ..., as 1, as) for a digital range, a vanilla call spread, and a vanilla put spread to form replication sets for each of these derivatives strategies. For the replication weights of additional derivatives strategies using the digital replication basis, see section 10.2.
A digital range or range binary pays out a specified amount if, upon expiration, the underlying U
is greater than or equal to a lower strike, denoted by k,,, and strictly less than a higher strike, denoted by k",. The payout function d for this digital range is 0 U < ky d (U) = 1 k,, <_ U < kW 11.1.3 C
0 k", S U
For a buy order of a digital range with strike prices of k" and kW the replicating weights are -3~3-0 s=1,2, ...;v a, = 1 s=v+l,v+2,...,w 11.1:3D
0 s=w+l,w+2,...,5 A'buy of avanilla call spread is the simultaneous buy of a vanilla call with a lower strike k,, and the sell of a vanilla call with a higher strike kw. The payout function d for this vanilla call spread is 0 U < ky d (U) = U - ky k,, < U < kW 11.1.3E
kw - kv kw < U
For a buy order for a vanilla call spread with strikes of k,, and 1~, the replicating weights are 0 s=1,2,...,v a,= k'-'+~s p-ky s=v+l,v+2,...,w 11.1.3F
k", - ky s=w+l,w+2,...,5 based on the intrastate uniform model of equation 11.1.3B.
A buy of a vanilla put spread is the simultaneous buy of a vanilla put with a higher strike k", and the sell of a vanilla put with a lower strike I~,. The payout function d for this vanilla put spread is kw - ky U < kv d (U) = kW - U kv s U < kw 11.1.36 0 k~, < U
For a buy order of a vanilla put spread with strikes of kW and k,, the replicating weights are -30~-kW - ky s=1,2,...,v a,= kw-ks-'+~s p s=v+l,v+2,...,w 11.1.3H
0' s=w+l,w+2,...,5 based on the intrastate uniform model of equation 11.1.3B.
11.1.4 Replication P&L
Let e(U) denote the payout on the replicating portfolio based on the replication weights (ai, a2, ..., as_t, as) for strategy d. Note that e(U) can be written as s e(U) ---- ~ asd' (U) s _ ~ 1[k,-, <- U < ks ]a~ 11.1.4A
where I denotes the indicator function, equaling one when its argument is true and zero otherwise. Let CR(U) denote the replication P&L to the auction sponsor (note that section 10 uses the variable C to denote replication P&L). If CR(U) is positive (negative), then the auction sponsor receives a profit (a loss) from the replication of the strategy. The replication P&L CR(U) is given by the following formula for a buy order of the strategy d with a minimum payout of 0 CR (U) ---- e(U) - d (U) s _ ~ 1[ks_, <_ U < kJ ] [a, - d (U)] 11.1.4B
s=~
Note that for a digital range, equations 11.1.3C and 11.1.3D imply that replication P&L CR(U) is zero regardless of the outcome of U. However, for each of a vanilla call spread and a vanilla put - 30~ -spread the replication P&L CR(U) will generally be non-zero. The replication P&L for a vanilla call spread is s CR (U) _ ~ I (k,~_, <- U < ks ] LaJ - d (U)]
s=~
'" k + k - p _ ~ I[kJ-, <_ U < ks ] s-' s - ky - (U - ky ) s=,.+~ 2 w _ ~ Ijks-, S U < ks ] kJ-' + k, p - U 11.1.4C
s=v+~ 2 These results hold more generally. When using the digital replication basis, the auction sponsor replicates digital strategies with zero replication P&L, whereas the auction sponsor replicates vanilla options with non-zero replication P&L.
11.2 Replicating Claims Using A Vanilla Replicating Basis This section discusses how to replicate derivatives strategies using a vanilla replicating basis.
Section 11.2.1 discusses the assumptions behind this framework. Section 11.2.2 defines the vanilla replicating basis. Section 11.2.3 presents the general replication theorem, in order to form replication sets for any type of derivatives strategy as a function of the payout profile or payout function d of the derivatives strategy, the replication sets including one or more of the replicating vanilla options, and sometimes a replicating digital option, as well. Using this theorem, section 11.2.4 shows how an auction sponsor can replicate digital derivatives, and section 11.2.5 shows how an auction sponsor can replicate vanilla derivatives.
11.2.1 Assumptions This section discusses the five assumptions that will be used to derive the general replication theorem. These assumptions will later be relaxed in section 11.3.
-30~-The first assumption regards the spacing of the strikes k1, k2, -..., ks I of the different derivatives strategies Assumption 1: ks - ks-~ >_ 2 p s = 2, 3, ..., S -1 Assumption 1 requires the strikes to be set far enough apart such that at least two outcomes are between adjacent strikes.
Assumptions 2 and 3 relate to the distribution of the underlying U.
i0 Assumption 2: E[UZ ) < 00 Assumption 3: There do not exist a finite ko and kS such that Pr[U< Iro)=0 and Pr[ U > ks)=Q.
Assumption 2 requires the second moment of U or equivalently the variance of U
to be finite.
Assumption 3 requires that the underlying U has only unbounded support.
Assumptions 4 and 5 regard the payout on the derivatives strategy d. Assume that d takes on the following form s Assumption 4: d (U) _ ~ I[k,-, 5 U < kJ )(a, + /3,U) J=I
This assumption restricts d to be a piecewise linear fimction.
For notation, let d and d denote functions of the derivatives strategy d computed as follows d = max[ d (U) , E[d (U) ~ U >_ kS_, ), E[d (U) ~ U < k, )] 11.2.1A
x,su~ts_, -3~7-d = min[ d (U) , E[d (U) ~ U >_ ks-, ), E[d (U) ~ U < k, ]] 11.2.1B
k,SU<ks_, In many cases as shown below, d will be the maximum payout of the derivatives strategy d and d will be the minimum payout of the derivatives strategy d.
Assumption S is as follows Assumption 5: d 5 a, + ~3,k, _< d s = 2, 3, ..., S -1 This assumption ensures that the replication weights defined in section 11.2.3 are non-negative.
Strategies that satisfy assumptions 4 and S include digital calls, digital puts, range binaries, vanilla calls, vanilla puts, vanilla call spreads, vanilla put spreads, vanilla straddles, collared vanilla straddles, forwards, and collared forwards.
11.2.2 The Vanilla Replicating Basis This section introduces the vanilla replicating basis based on the assumptions in section 11.2.1.
The vanilla replicating basis has a total of 2S 2 replication claims, compared to S replicating claims for the digital replicating basis. Note that the quantity 2S 2 is twice the number of defined strikes in a DBAR auction. The term "vanilla replicating basis" is something of a misnomer because two of these replicating claims are digital options.
Several of the replicating claims described below have a knockout or burner.
All of these knockouts are European style, i.e. they are only in effect on expiration of the option, and thus do not depend on the path of the underlying over the life of the option.
Let d~ denote the payout function for the vanilla replication claims for s=1, 2, ..., 2S 2. The first vanilla replicating claim is a digital put with strike k1 with payout function 1 U < k, d (U) = 0 k1 < U 11.2.2A
- 30~ -The second replicating claim has the following payout function 0 U < k, d 2 (U) = k2 U k, S U < k2 11.2.2B
kz - ki 0 k2 S U
The payout of the second replicating claim is proportional to that of a vanilla put struck at k2 which has a European knockout below k1. Note that the second replicating claim has a payout of 1 at U--kl. The third replicating claim has a payout that is proportional to a vanilla call struck at k1 which has a European knock out at k2. Mathematically, 0 U < k, d3 (U) = U k, k, <_ U < k2 11.2.2C
k2 - k, 0 k2 <_ U
In the general case for s=2, 3, ..., S 1 0 U < kJ_, d2s-z (U) = ks U ks-, S U < kJ 11.2.2D
ka - ks-1 0 ks S U
0 U < k,-, U-k d 2s-' (U) = k -k -' ks_, S.U < k, 11.2.2E
s s-1 0 ks <_ U
For the s=2S-4 and s=2S-3 the replication claims are -30~-0 U < ks_z d2s-a(U) = ks-' -U ks-z < U < ks_, 11.2.2F
ks_~ _ ks_z 0 ks_, <_ U
0 U < ks_z d2s-3 (U) = U ks-2 kS-2 _< U < ks_, ~11.Z.ZG
ks-i - ks-2 0 ks_, < U
S Note that the even-numbered replicating claims have a negatively sloped payout between the .
strikes, similar to standard vanilla puts. The odd-numbered replicating claims have a positively sloped payout between the strikes similar to standard vanilla calls. The 2S
2"d replicating claim is a digital call struck at ks I.
dzs-z(U)= 0 U < ks_, 11.2.2H
1 ks_, <_ U
Figure 31 and table 11.2.2 shows the vanilla replicating claims.
It is worth noting that the.vanilla replicating claims are rescaled in such a way that for all U

~ds(U)=1 11.2.2I
This feature will be used later in section 11.4.3, where the sum of the prices of the replicating claims are required to sum to one.
Table 11.2.2: The payout ranges and replicating claims for the vanilla replicating basis.
.. 310 Claim Payout European Number Ran a Vanilla Re licatin Claim Knockout?

1 U < k1 Di 'tal ut struck at ki None 2 k1 <- U< Rescaled vanilla ut struckKnockout at k~-k2 at k2 3 k1 <_ U Rescaled vanilla call Knockout at k2 < k2 struck at k1 4 k2 < U Rescaled vanilla ut struckKnockout at k2-< k3 at k3 k2 < U Rescaled vanilla call Knockout at k3 < k3 struck at k2 2s-2 kS_~ < Rescaled vanilla ut struckKnockout at ks_1-U< ks at ks 2s-1 ks_1 _< escaled vanilla call struckKnockout at ks U < ks at ks_1 R

2s ks_<< U< Rescaled vanilla ut struckKnockout at ks kr~l at k,~~

2s+1 ks < U Rescaled vanilla call Knockout at ks.+.1 < ks.,-~ struck at ks 2S-4 kS 2 -< Rescaled vanilla ut struckKnockout at ks U < ks at ks_1 2-i 2S 3 . ks_Z:-< Rescaled vanilla call Knockout at k~l U< ks struck at ks_2 ~

2S 2 ks_~ <- Di 'tal call struck at None U ks 1 As seen in the table above, it is worth noting that with the vanilla replication basis, two such claims often payout if the underlying is in a specific range. This distinguishes this basis from the digital replicating basis discussed in section 11.1 where only one replicating claim pays out 5 regardless of the outcome of U.
11.2.3 General Replication Theorem for Buys and Sells of Digital and Vanilla Derivatives The following theorem shows how to construct the weights on the vanilla replicating portfolio denoted as (al, a2, ..., a2s_3, azs_2) of strategies d that satisfy the assumptions above.
General Replication Theorem. Under assumptions 1, 2, 3, 4, and S, the variance minimizing replicating weights for a buy of strategy d are a, =a, +~3,E[U~U<k,]-d 11.2.3A
az,_z = as + ~, kJ-~ - d s = 2, 3, ..., S -1 11.2.3B
azs-, =as +~3sks -d s=2,3,...,5-1. 11.2.3C

azs-z = as + ~s~U ~ U ? ks-1 ] - d 11.2.3D
For a sell of strategy d, the variance minimizing weights are a,=d-a,-~i,E[U~U<k,) 11.2.3E
az,,-z = 'd - a, - ~3$ ks-, s = 2, 3, ..., S -1 11.2.3F
azJ-, = d -czs -,13,k, s = 2, 3, ..., 5 -1 11.2.36 azs-z = d - as - ~sE[U ~ U >_ ks-, ] 11.2.3H
The replication P&L CR(U) for a buy of d is 1 S CR (U) _ ~3, (U - E[U ( U < k, ])I[U < k, ] + j3s (E[U ~ U >_ ks-, ] -U)IjU >- ks_, ] 11.2.3I
The replication P&L CR(U) for a sell of d is CR (U) _ ~, (E[U ~ U < k, ] - U)I[U < k, ] + ~(3s (U - E[U ~ U ? ks-, ])I[U ?
ks-, ] 11.2.3) Proof of General Replication Theorem: See Appendix 11A.
Appendix 11A shows that the replication weights for a buy of d or a sell of d satisfy min(al, a2, ..., a2s_3, azs-2~-0 11.2.3K
Since the a's are non-negative, this ensures that aggregated customer payouts (the y's defined in section 11.4.5) are also non-negative.

Note that the payout on the replicating portfolio for a buy of d plus the payout on the replicating portfolio for a sell of d equals d -d for all values of U. Thus the payout on the replicating portfolio with a buy of d and a sell of d is constant and so, as expected, the portfolio is risk free.
Consider the special case where as defined in assumption 4, d satisfies y =~3s =0 11.2.3L
In this case, the payout of the derivatives strategy is constant and equal to al if the underlying U
is less than k1. Similarly, the payout of the derivatives strategy is constant and equal to as if the underlying U is greater than or equal to ks_I. Under 11.2.3L, the replicating portfolio is not only minimum variance but also has replication P&L C'R(UJ=0 for every outcome U.
This result applies.to digital calls, digital puts, range binaries, vanilla call spreads, vanilla put spreads, collared vanilla straddles, and collared forwards. The vanilla replicating basis replicates these instruments with zero replication P&L.
The next section applies the general replication theorem to compute the vanilla replicating weights for different digital derivatives strategies d.
11.2.4 Using the General Replication Theorem to Compute Replication Weights for Digital Options To apply the general replication theorem above for digital derivatives strategies, note that for the digital options discussed below d =1 and d =0. Further, digital options have the following parameters restrictions ~~ =~z =~~~=~s =0 11.2.4A

In addition, a, will equal zero or one for s=l, 2, ..., S.
The payout function d for a digital call with a strike price of k,, is 0 U < ky d (U) = 1 ky < U 11.2.4B
For a buy order of a digital call with a strike price of k,, the replicating weights are a$ = 0 s=1,2,...,2v-1 11.2.4C
1 s=2v,2v+1,...,25-2 For.a sell order ofa digital call with a strike price of k,, the replicating weights are 1 s=1,2,...,2v.-1 as = 11.2.4D
0 s=2v,2v+1,...,25-2 A digital put pays out a specific quantity if the underlying is strictly below the strike, denoted kv, on expiration, and therefore its payout function d is 1 U < k,, d (U) = 11.2.4E
0 ky < U
For a buy order of a digital put with a strike price of k,, the replicating weights are 1 s =1, 2, ..., 2v-1 as = 11.2.4F
0 s = 2v, 2v + 1, ..., 2S - 2 For a sell order of a digital put with a strike price of k,, the replicating weights are 0 s=1,2,...,2v-1 as = . 11.2.46 1 s=2v,2v+1,...,25-2 As defined in section 11.1.3, the payout function for a digital range with strikes k" and 1~, can be represented as 0 U < k,, d(U)= 1 k" <-U<kW 11.2.4II
0 k", _< U
For a buy order of a digital range with strikes kv and 1~, the replicating weights are 0 s=1,2,...,2v-1 as = 1 s=2v,2v+1,...,2w-1 11.2.4I
0 s=2w,2w+1,...,25-2 One can contrast equation 11.2.4I to equation 11.1.3D, which shows the replicating weights for a digital range with the digital replicating basis. For a sell order of a digital range with strikes k,, and kw the replicating weights are 1 s=1,2,...,2v-1 a, = 0 s=2v,2v+1,...,2w-1 11.2.4) 1 s=2w,2w+1,...,25-2 11.2.5 Using the General Replication Theorem to Compute Replication Weights for Vanilla Derivatives This section uses the general replication theorem to compute vanilla replication weights for vanilla derivatives. Note that for vanilla derivatives, /3S equals 0 or 1 for s=1, 2, ..., S. In addition, for all the vanilla derivatives strategies described below, excluding forwards and collared forwards, d=0. For notation, let the function int[x) denote the greatest integer less than or equal to x.
-3~5-Replicating Vanilla Call Options and Vanilla Put Options The payout function d for a vanilla call with strike k,, is 0 U<ky d (U) = U - kV kV < U 11.2.5A
Note that in this case, d = 0 and d = E[U ( U ? ks-, ] - k,, . For a buy order for a vanilla call with strike I~, the replication weights are 0 s = l, 2,...,2v-1 as= km~~s+,~,z~-ky s=2v,2v+1,...,25-3 11.2.5B
E[U~U>-ks_,]-ky s=2S-2 For a sell order for a vanilla call with strike k,, the replication weights are E[U~U>-ks-,] - k,, s=1,2,...,2v-1 as = E[U~U>-ks_,] -kma~s+~>iz~ s=2v,2v+1,...,2S-3 11.2.5C
0 s=ZS-2 The payout function d for a vanilla put with strike k" is k~ - U U < kv d (U) = 0 k < U 11.2.5D
y Note that in this case, d = 0 and d = kv - E[U ~ U < k, ] . For a buy order for a vanilla put with strike k,, the replication weights are ky-E[U~U<k,] s=1 aJ = k"-km~~s+,>~z~ s=2,3,...,2v-1 11.2.5E
0 s=2v,2v+1,...,25-2 For a sell order for a vanilla put with strike k,, the replication weights are 0 s=1 S as = km~~s+,>~z~ - E[U ~ U < k, ) s = 2, 3, . . . , 2v -1 11.2.5F
k,,-E[U~U<ki] s=2v,2v+1,...,25-2 Replicating Vanilla Call Spreads and Vanilla Put Spreads As discussed in section 11.1.3, the payout function d for a vanilla call spread with strikes k,, and k~, is 0 U<kv d (U) = U - ky k,, <_ U < kW 11.2.56 k", - k" kW <- U
For this strategy, note that d = 0 and d = kw - ky . For a buy order for a vanilla call spread with strikes of k,, and kW the replicating weights are 0 s=1,2,...,2v-1 a, = k~~~s+,~~z~ -kv s=2v,2v+1,...,2w-1 11.2.5H
kW - kv s=2w,2w+1,...,25-2 One can contrast equation 11.2.5H to equation 11.1.3F, which shows the replicating weights for a vanilla call spread with the digital replicating basis. For a sell order for a vanilla call spread with strikes of k,, and kW the replicating weights are kw - ky s = l, 2, ..., 2v -1 as .= kw -kma~s+,~~z~ s = 2v, 2v+1,..., 2w-1 11.2.5I
0 s=2w,2w+1,...,25-2 Again, as discussed in section 11.1.3, the payout function d for a buy of a vanilla put spread with strikes kw and k" is kW - ky U < ky d (U) = kW - U kV <- U < kw 11.2.5J
0 kw < U
For a vanilla put spread, note that d = 0 and d = kw - k,, , which are identical values for d to d for a vanilla call spread. For a buy order for a vanilla put spread with strikes of 1~,, and !~, the replicating weights are kw - k,, s=1,2,...,2v-1 as = kw -k;~u~s+,~~z~ s = 2v, 2v+1,..., 2w-1 11.2.5K
0 s=2w,2w+1,...,25-2 One can contrast equation 11.2.5K to equation 11.1.3H, which shows the replicating weights for a vanilla put spread with the digital replicating basis. For a sell order for a vanilla put spread with strikes of kw and k" the replicating weights are 0 s=1,2,...,2v-1 km~~s+,>~z~ -k,, s = 2v, 2v+1,..., 2w-1 11.2.5L
kW - k~ s=2w,2w+1,...,25-2 Replicating Vanilla Straddles and Collared Vanilla Straddles -31~-A buy of a vanilla straddle is the simultaneous buy of a vanilla call and a vanilla put both with identical strike prices. A buy of a vanilla straddle is a bullish volatility strategy, in that the purchaser profits if the outcome is very low or very high.
For a vanilla straddle with a strike of kV, the payout function d is ky-U U<ky d (U) = U - ky ky < U 11.2.5M
Note'that for this strategy d = max(E[U ( U >- ks-, ] - k,, , k,, - E[U ( U <
k, ]) and d = 0 .
Therefore, for a buy of a vanilla straddle k,,-E[U~U<k~] s=1 k,, - kmu~,+m z~ s = 2, 3, ..., 2v -1 11.2.5N
as =
kmr~~s+,~iz~-ky s=2v,2v+1,...;25-3 E[U~U>_ks-,]-ky s=2S-2 For a sell of a vanilla straddle the replicating weights are d =ky+E[U~U.<k,] s=1 d - ky + km~~s+l~iz~ s = 2, 3, ..., 2v -1 a= = 11.2.50 d -kmu~J+~>~z~+k,, s=2v,2v+1,...,25-3 d -E[U~U>-ks_,]+k~ s=2S-2 To avoid taking on replication risk, the auction sponsor may offer participants the ability to instead trade a collared vanilla straddle whose payout can be written as kv - k, U < k, k,, - U k, S U < kv d(U)= U-k k _<U<k 11.2.5P
s-t ks-, - ky ks_, <- U
-31~-Note that d = max[ks_, -k,,,k,, -k, ] for a collared vanilla straddle and ~d~=
0 .
For a buy order of a collared vanilla straddle with strike kV, the replicating weights are k"-k, s=1 k,, -kmu~s+,>,z~ s = 2, 3,..., 2v-1 as = 11.2.5Q
k~u~s+,>~z~ -ky s = 2v, 2v+1,..., 2S-3 ks_, - k,, s = 2S - 2 Therefore, for a sell order of a vanilla straddle with strike k,, the replicating weights are max[ks_,-ky,ky-k,]-ky+k, s=1 max[ks_, - ky, k,, - k, ] - k,, + k~~,+,>~z~ s = 2, 3, ..., 2v -1 as = 11.2.58 max[ks_, - k", ky - k, ] - k;~u~s+,~~z~ + k,, s = 2v, 2v + 1, ..., 2S - 3 max[ks-, - ky, ky - k, ] - ks_, + ky s = 2S - 2 Replicating Forwards and Collared Forwards A forward pays out based on the underlying as follows d(U) = U-~f 11.2.5S
where ~ denotes the forward price. Note that for a forward, d = E[U ~ U >-kS_, ] - ~ f and d = E[U ~ U < k,]-~cf . In this case, for a buy of a forward 0 s=1 a, = k;~u~s+,>iz~-E[U~U<k,] s=2,3,...,25-3 11.2.5T
E[U~U>-ks_,]-E[U~U<k,] s=2S-2 For a sell of a forward E[U[U>_ks-,]-E[U[U<k,] s=1 as = E[U [ U >- ks-, ] - kma~,+,>iz~ s = 2, 3, . . . , 2S - 3 11.2.5U
0 s=2S-2 To avoid taking on replication P&L, the auction sponsor may offer a collared forward strategy with maximum and minimum payouts. Let ~~ denote the price on the collared forward. For a buy order of a collared forward, the payout function d is k, - ~r'f U < k, d(U)= U-~c~ k, <U<ks, 11.2.5V
ks-~ - ~ ~ km ~ U
1n this case, note that d = ks_, - ~c ~ and d = k, - ~ ~ . For a buy of a collared forward the replicating weights are 0 s=1 as = k;~,~~s+,>~2~ - k, s = 2, 3, ..., 2S - 3 11.2.5W
ks-, - k, s -_ 2S - 2 , For a sell of a collared forward the replicating weights are ks-i - ki s =1 as = ks-, - km~cs+,~iz~ s = 2, 3, ..., 2S - 3 11.2.5X
0 s=2S-2 It is worth noting that there is possibly infinite replication risk for vanilla calls and vanilla puts, vanilla straddles, and forwards.
Estimating the Conditional Expectation of the Underlying - 32 ~ -Note that for buys and sells of vanilla calls, vanilla puts, vanilla straddles, and forwards, some of the replicating weights depend upon E[U ( U < k, ] and E[U ~ U >_ ks_, ] .
These two quantities could be estimated, for example, using a non parametric approach based on a historical data sample on the underlying as follows. The auction sponsor could use the average of the S observations below k, to estimate E[U ~ U < k, ) , and the auction sponsor could use the average of the observations greater than or equal to ks-, to estimate E[U ~ U >_ ks-, ] . Alternatively, the auction sponsor could estimate these 'quantities parametrically assuming that U follows a certain distribution. To select the appropriate distribution for U, the auction sponsor might employ techniques from Section 10.3.1 in the subsections "Classes of Distributions for the Underlying,"
and "Selecting the Appropriate Distribution."
For the case that Uis normally distributed, recall equation 10.3.1B from section 10 \ka-~ - /u)2 ~ks - f ) 27t ex 26 2 ex 26 Z
E[U ~ ks _ t _< U < ks J = fc + 11.2.5Y
N ks -,u - N ks-, - fc Q
where ~ denotes the constant 3.14159..., where Ndenotes the cumulative normal distribution, and where "exp" denotes the exponential function or raising the argument to the power of e.
Letting ks_1 ~ -oo and setting ks equal to k~, then equation 11.2.5Y
simplifies to ~ ~k~ _ f~) 2 2~c exp 2a~z E[U~U<k,]_,u- 11.2.52 N k~ - ~
Letting ks -~ oo and setting ks_1 equal to kS_~, then equation 11.2.5Y
simplifies to 6 exp - ~ks-' f~)2 E[U ~ ks-, < U] - fc + 2~ k 2~z 11.2.SAA
1 _ NC S_~ _ f~

To estimate the parameters of the distribution of U such as ft and a-above, the auction sponsor might employ techniques discussed in Section 10.3.1 in the subsection "Estimating the Parameters of the Distribution."
11.3 Extensions to the General Replication Theorem Section 11.2.1 discusses the five assumptions used to derive the general replication theorem.
This section discusses how relaxing these assumptions impacts the theorem.
11.3.1 Relaxing Assumption 1 on Strike Spacing Assumption 1 is ks - ks-, >_ 2 p s = 2, 3, ..., S -1 11.3.1 A
What happens when strikes are closer together and this assumption is violated while assumptions 2, 3,, 4, and 5 still hold?
Remember that an example embodiment may assume that the strikes are multiples of the tick size p. Consider the special case where 11.3.1 A holds for all values of s except s=2 and k2=k,+p 11.3.1B
In this case, the first vanilla replicating claim is the digital put struck at k~, which is the first replicating claim from section 11.2.2. The second vanilla replicating claim is the rescaled European vanilla put struck at k2 that knocks out at k1- p. Note that since k1 and k2 are spaced p apart as dictated by 11.3.1 B, this replicating claim pays out 1 at k~ and zero otheawise.

DEMANDE OU BREVET VOLUMINEUX
LA PRESENTE PARTIE DE CETTE DEMANDE OU CE BREVET COMPREND
PLUS D'UN TOME.

NOTE : Pour les tomes additionels, veuillez contacter 1e Bureau canadien des brevets JUMBO APPLICATIONS/PATENTS
THIS SECTION OF THE APPLICATION/PATENT CONTAINS MORE THAN ONE
VOLUME

NOTE: For additional volumes, please contact the Canadian Patent Office NOM DU FICHIER / FILE NAME
NOTE POUR LE TOME / VOLUME NOTE:

Claims (88)

What is claimed is:
1. A method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering comprising:
enabling at least two types of bets to be offered in a common betting pool;
and offering at least one of the two types of enabled bets to bettors.
2. The method according to claim 1, further comprising the step of:
selecting an underlying event for the common betting pool.
3. The method according to claim 2, wherein the selecting step includes the step of selecting one of a sporting event, a lottery, and a horse race as the underlying event.
4. The method according to claim 2, wherein the selecting step includes the step of:
selecting a horse race as the underlying event.
5. The method according to claim 4, wherein the enabling step includes the step of:
selecting at least one of the at least two types of bets from the group consisting of a win bet, a bet on a horse to finish in one or more places, a place bet, a show bet, an exacta bet, a perfecta bet, a quinella bet, a trifecta bet, a boxed trifecta bet, wheeling a horse, and a bet against a horse finishing in one or more places.
6. The method according to claim 1, further comprising the step of:
accepting a bet on one of the at least two types of enabled bets into the common betting pool.
7. The method according to claim 1, wherein the enabling step includes the step of:
enabling limit odds to be placed on the at least two types of bets offered in the common betting pool.
8. A method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering comprising:
enabling at least one type of bet with limit odds to be offered in a betting pool; and offering the at least one type of enabled limit odds bet to bettors.
9. A method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering, comprising:
establishing a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of an underlying event;
receiving an indication of limit odds, a premium, and a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of the plurality of fundamental outcomes; and determining a payout as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the premium and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes.
10. The method according to claim 9, wherein the determining step includes the steps of:
determining final odds as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the premium and the total amount wagered; and determining the payout as a function of the final odds and the premium.
11. A method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering, comprising:
establishing a plurality of fundamental outcomes in a betting pool, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of an underlying event;
receiving an indication of limit odds, a premium, and a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of the plurality of fundamental outcomes; and determining final odds as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the premium and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes in the betting pool.
12. The method according to claim 11, further comprising the step of:
accepting at least part of the premium into the betting pool if the final odds are equal to the limit odds.
13. The method according to claim 12, further comprising the step of:
accepting all of the premium into the betting pool if the final odds are greater than the limit odds.
14. The method according to claim 11, further comprising the step of:

determining a filled premium as a function of the final odds and the limit odds.
15. The method according to claim 14, further comprising the step of:
determining a payout as a function of the filled premium and the final odds.
16. The method according to claim 11, further comprising the step of:
establishing a betting period.
17. The method according to claim 16, wherein the receiving step includes the step of:
receiving a bet prior to an end of the betting period, the bet including the indication of the limit odds, the premium, and the selected outcome.
18. The method according to claim 17, further comprising the step of:
executing the bet if the final odds are one of greater than and equal to the limit odds.
19. The method according to claim 17, further comprising the step of:
receiving at least one additional bet prior to an end of the betting period, each of the at least one additional bet including an indication of a selected outcome, limit odds, and one of a premium and a desired payout.
20. The method according to claim 19, wherein the step of receiving the at least one additional bet, includes the step of receiving an indication of limit odds equal to zero for one of the at least one additional bets, the one bet being equivalent to a traditional bet excluding an indication of the limit odds.
21. The method according to claim 20, wherein the determining step includes the step of:
determining final odds for each additional bet as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the one of the premium and the desired payout for the additional bet, and the total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes in the betting pool.
22. The method according to claim 21, wherein the determining step includes the step of:

determining the total amount wagered in the betting pool as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the final odds, and the premium for the bet, arid the selected outcome, the limit odds, the final odds, and the one of the premium and the desired payout for each of the at least one additional bet.
23. The method according to claim 22, wherein the step of determining the total amount wagered, includes the step of:
determining the total amount wagered in the betting pool as a further function of opening bets on each of the fundamental outcomes in the betting pool.
24. The method according to claim 23, further comprising the step of:
placing opening bets on each of the fundamental outcomes in the betting pool, each opening bet including an indication of an opening premium on the fundamental outcome for the opening bet.
25. The method according to claim 21, wherein the step of receiving the at least one additional bet, includes the step of:
for each of the at least one additional bets including an indication of a premium, categorizing the additional bet as a premium bet; and for each of the at least one additional bets including an indication of a desired payout, categorizing the additional bet as a payout bet.
26. The method according to claim 25, further comprising the step of:
determining a filled premium for the bet as a function of the final odds and the limit odds for the bet; and determining a filled payout for the bet as a function of the final odds and the filled premium.
27. The method according to claim 26, further comprising the steps of:
determining, for each additional premium bet, a filled premium as a function of the final odds and the limit odds for the additional premium bet;

determining, for each additional premium bet, a filled payout as a function of the final odds and the filled premium;
determining, for each additional payout bet, a filled payout as a function of the final odds and the limit odds for the additional payout bet; and determining, for each additional payout bet, a filled premium as a function of the final odds and the filled payout.
28. A method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering, comprising:
establishing a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of an underlying event;
receiving an indication of limit odds, a desired payout, and a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of the plurality of fundamental outcomes; and determining a premium as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the desired payout and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes.
29. The method according to claim 28, wherein the determining step includes the steps of:
determining final odds as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the desired payout and the total amount wagered; and determining the premium as a function of the final odds and the premium.
30. A method for conducting enhanced parimutuel wagering, comprising:
establishing a plurality of fundamental outcomes in a betting pool, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of an underlying event;
receiving an indication of limit odds, a desired payout, and a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of the plurality of fundamental outcomes; and determining final odds as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the desired payout and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes in the betting pool.
31. The method according to claim 30, further comprising the step of:
accepting at least part of the desired payout into the betting pool if the final odds are equal to the limit odds.
32. The method according to claim 31, further comprising the step of:.
accepting all of the desired payout into the betting pool if the final odds are greater than the limit odds.
33. The method according to claim 30, further comprising the step of:
determining a filled payout as a function of the final odds and the limit odds.
34. The method according to claim 33, further comprising the step of:.
determining a filled premium as a function of the final odds and the filled payout.
35. The method according to claim 30, further comprising the step of:
establishing a betting period.
36. The method according to claim 35, wherein the receiving step includes the step of:
receiving a bet prior to an end of the betting period, the bet including the indication of the limit odds, the desired payout, and the selected outcome.
37. The method according to claim 36, further comprising the step of:
executing the bet if the final odds are one of greater than and equal to the limit odds.
38. The method according to claim 36, further comprising the step of:
receiving at least one additional bet prior to an end of the betting period, each of the at least one additional bet including an indication of a selected outcome, limit odds, and one of a premium and a desired payout.
39. The method according to claim 38, wherein the step of receiving the at least one additional bet, includes the step of:
receiving an indication of limit odds equal to zero for one of the at least one additional bets, the one bet being equivalent to a traditional bet excluding an indication of the limit odds.
40. The method according to claim 39, wherein the determining step includes the step of:

determining final odds for each additional bet as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the one of the premium and the desired payout for the additional bet, and the total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes in the betting pool.
41. The method according to claim 40, wherein the determining step includes the step of:
determining the total amount wagered in the betting pool as a function of the selected outcome, the limit odds, the final odds, and the desired payout for the bet, and the selected outcome, the limit odds, the final odds, and the one of the premium and the desired payout for each of the at least one additional bet.
42. The method according to claim 41, wherein the step of determining the total amount wagered, includes the step of:
determining the total amount wagered in the betting pool as a further function of opening bets on each of the fundamental outcomes in the betting pool.
43. A method for processing a bet in an enhanced parimutuel betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool including at least one bet, comprising:
establishing fundamental outcomes in a betting pool, each one of the fundamental outcomes corresponding to at least one possible outcome of the underlying event;
establishing fundamental bets on each fundamental outcome in the betting pool;
configuring an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for the bet as a function of a selected outcome for the bet, the selected outcome for the bet corresponding to at least one fundamental outcome; and determining at least one of a premium and a payout for the wager as a function of a demand-based valuation of each fundamental bet in the equivalent combination for the wager.
44. A method for processing a bet in an enhanced parimutuel betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool including at least one wager, comprising:
establishing fundamental outcomes in a betting pool, each one of the fundamental outcomes corresponding to at least one possible outcome of the underlying event;
establishing fundamental bets on each fundamental outcome in the betting pool;

configuring an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for the wager as a function of a selected outcome for the wager, the selected outcome for the wager corresponding to at least one fundamental outcome; and determining a price for each fundamental bet as a function of a price of each of the other fundamental bets in the betting pool, a total filled amount in each fundamental outcome, and a total amount wagered in the plurality of fundamental outcomes in the betting pool.
45. The method according to claim 44, wherein the configuring step includes the step of:
determining a weight of each fundamental bet in the equivalent combination as a function of the selected outcome for the wager.
46. The method according to claim 45, wherein the weight determining step includes the step of:
determining the weight of each fundamental bet in the equivalent combination as a further function of relative desired payouts for different selected outcomes in the wager.
47. The method according to claim 45, further comprising the step of:
determining a price for the wager as a function of the price and weight of each fundamental bet in the equivalent combination.
48. The method according to claim 47, further comprising the step of:
receiving an indication of a premium for the wager.
49. The method according to claim 48, further comprising the step of:
determining a payout for the wager as a function of the premium and the price for the wager.
50. The method according to claim 47, further comprising the step of:
receiving an indication of a desired payout for the wager.
51. The method according to claim 50, further comprising the step of:

determining a premium for the wager as a function of desired payout and the price for the wager.
52. The method according to claim 47, further comprising the step of:
determining final odds for the wager as a function of the price for the wager.
53. The method according to claim 52, further comprising the step of:
receiving an indication of limit odds for the wager.
54. The method according to claim 53, further comprising the steps of:
receiving an indication of a requested premium for the wager; and determining a filled premium for the wager as a function of the requested premium and a comparison of the final odds and the limit odds.
55. The method according to claim 54, further comprising the step of:
determining a filled payout for the wager as a function of the filled premium and the price for the wager.
56. The method according to claim 54, wherein the step of determining the price of each fundamental bet includes the step of:
determining the total amount wagered in the betting pool by summing up the filled premium for the wager, a filled premium for each additional wager in the betting pool, and a premium for an opening order on all of the fundamental bets in the betting pool.
57. The method according to claim 53, further comprising the steps of:
receiving an indication of a desired payout for the wager; and determining a filled payout for the wager as a function of the desired payout and a comparison of the final odds and the limit odds.
58. The method according to claim 57, further comprising the step of":
determining a filled premium for the wager as a function of the filled payout and the price for the wager.
59. The method according to claim 58, wherein the step of determining the price of each fundamental bet includes the step of:
determining the total amount wagered in the betting pool by summing up the filled premium for the wager, a premium for each additional wager in the betting pool, and a premium for an opening order on all of the fundamental bets in the betting pool.
60. The method according to claim 59, wherein the step of establishing fundamental outcomes in the betting pool, includes the step of:
establishing the fundamental outcomes in the betting pool as mutually exclusive possible outcomes of the underlying event.
61. The method according to claim 60, wherein the step of determining the price of each fundamental bet includes the steps of:
determining a filled amount for each fundamental bet in each fundamental outcome by summing up a product of the weight of the fundamental bet in the equivalent combination for the wager with the filled payout for the wager, and products, for each additional wager in the betting pool, of weights of the fundamental bet in an equivalent combination for the additional wager and a filled payout for the additional wager.
62. The method according to claim 61, wherein the step of determining the price of each fundamental bet includes the steps of:
determining, for each fundamental bet, an opening fill by dividing a premium on an opening wager on the fundamental bet by the price of the fundamental bet;
determining, for each fundamental bet, a total filled amount for the fundamental bet by adding the opening fill to the filled amount; and equating, for each fundamental bet, the total amount wagered in the betting pool in all of the fundamental outcomes with the total filled amount for the fundamental bet.
63. The method according to claim 62, wherein the step of determining the price of each fundamental bet includes the step of:

performing an iteration by repeating the steps of determining a price for each fundamental bet in the betting pool, and determining the final odds, the filled premium and the filled payout for the wager and for each additional wager in the betting pool, determining the total amount wagered in all of the fundamental outcomes in the betting pool and the total filled amount for each fundamental bet and equating the total amount wagered in the betting pool with the total filled amount for each fundamental bet, until reaching a maximization of the total amount wagered in the betting pool.
64. The method according to claim 63, wherein the performing step includes the step of:
performing the iteration until satisfying a condition that, for each of the wager and additional wagers, the final odds are better than or equal to the limit odds for the wager.
65. A method for betting on an underlying event, comprising:
providing an indication of limit odds, a requested premium, and a selected outcome, for a bet on a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to a possible outcome of the underlying event; and receiving an indication of final odds for the bet, the final odds being determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of an equivalent combination of fundamental bets, the equivalent combination including at least one fundamental bet, each fundamental bet betting on a respective fundamental outcome, the equivalent combination being configured as a function of the selected outcome for the bet.
66. The method according to claim 65, further comprising the step of:
receiving an indication of a filled premium, the filled premium being determined as a function of the requested premium and a comparison of the final odds with the limit odds for the bet.
67. A method for betting on an underlying event, comprising:
providing an indication of limit odds, a desired payout, and a selected outcome, for a bet on a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to a possible outcome of the underlying event; and receiving an indication of final odds for the bet, the final odds being determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of an equivalent combination of fundamental bets, the equivalent combination including at least one fundamental bet, each fundamental bet betting on a respective fundamental outcome, the equivalent combination being configured as a function of the selected outcome for the bet.
68. The method according to claim 67, further comprising the step of:
receiving an indication of a filled payout, the filled payout being determined as a function of the desired payout and a comparison of the final odds with the limit odds for the bet.
69. A vehicle for betting in an enhanced parimutuel betting pool, comprising:
a wager betting a filled premium amount on a selected outcome of an underlying event, the wager including an indication of limit odds on the selected outcome, and one of a requested premium and a desired payout on the selected outcome, the filled premium being determined as a function of the one of the requested premium and the desired payout and a comparison of the limit odds with final odds on the wager, the final odds being determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of each of the fundamental bets in a combination of fundamental bets equivalent to the wager, the combination including at least one fundamental bet from a plurality of fundamental bets established for the betting pool, each fundamental bet betting on a fundamental outcome of the underlying event, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of the underlying event, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one fundamental outcome, and the combination of fundamental bets being configured as a function of the selected outcome of the wager.
70. The vehicle according to claim 69, wherein the wager is processed if the final odds are one of greater than and equal to the limit odds for the wager.
71. A computer system for conducting a betting pool on an underlying event, comprising:
at least one processor configured to:

establish fundamental outcomes for the underlying event, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of the event;
establish fundamental bets for the underlying event, each fundamental bet betting on a respective fundamental outcome;
receive an indication of limit odds, one of a requested premium and a desired payout, and a selected outcome, for a wager on a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to a possible outcome of the underlying event;
configure an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for the wager as a function of the selected outcome of the wager; and determine final odds for the wager by engaging in a demand-based valuation of the fundamental bets in the equivalent combination.
72. The computer system according to claim 71, further comprising:
at least one database module; and at least one terminal, the processor being operative with the at least one database module and the at least one terminal.
73. The computer system according to claim 72, further comprising:
a server housing the processor and the at least one database module; and a network connecting the at least one database module and the processor with the at least one terminal.
74. The computer system according to claim 71, wherein the at least one processor includes a first processor and a second processor parallel to the first processor.
75. The computer system according to claim 74, wherein the first processor operates with the second processor, each processor configured to at least one of establish the fundamental outcomes, establish the fundamental bets, receive the indication of limit odds, configure the equivalent combination, and determine the final odds for the wager.
76. A computer system for placing a bet in a betting pool on an underlying event, the computer system comprising:
at least one processor configured to:
providing an indication of limit odds, one of a desired payout and a requested premium, and a selected outcome, for a bet on a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to a possible outcome of the underlying event; and receiving an indication of final odds for the bet, the final odds being determined by engaging in a demand-based valuation of an equivalent combination of fundamental bets, the equivalent combination including at least one fundamental bet, each fundamental bet betting on a respective fundamental outcome, the equivalent combination being configured as a function of the selected outcome for the bet.
77. The computer system according to claim 76, wherein the at least one processor is further configured to:
place the bet if the final odds are greater than or equal to the limit odds.
78. A computer program product capable of processing a wager in a betting pool including at least one wager, the computer program product comprising a computer usable medium having computer readable program code embodied in the medium for causing a computer to:
establish fundamental outcomes for the underlying event, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of the event;
establish fundamental bets for the underlying event, each fundamental bet betting on a respective fundamental outcome;
receive an indication of limit odds, one of a requested premium and a desired payout, and a selected outcome, for a wager on a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to a possible outcome of the underlying event;
configure an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for the wager as a function of the selected outcome of the wager; and determine final odds for the wager by engaging in a demand-based valuation of the fundamental bets an the equivalent combination.
79. An article of manufacture comprising an information storage medium encoded with a computer-readable data structure adapted for placing a wager over the Internet in a betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool including at least one wager, said data structure comprising:
at least one data field with information identifying at least one selected outcome of an underlying event, limit odds, and one of a requested premium and a desired payout for the wager;
and at least one data field with information identifying final odds for the wager, the final odds being determined as a result of a demand-based valuation of fundamental bets in a combination of fundamental bets equivalent to the wager configured as a function of the selected outcome, the combination including at least one of the fundamental bets established for the betting pool, each fundamental bet betting on a fundamental outcome of the underlying event, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of the event, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one fundamental outcome.
80. An article of manufacture comprising a propagated signal adapted for use in the performance of a method for conducting a betting pool on an underlying event, the betting pool including at least one wager, a. The method comprising the steps of:
establishing fundamental outcomes for the underlying event, each fundamental outcome corresponding to at least one possible outcome of the event;
establishing fundamental bets for the underlying event, each fundamental bet betting on a respective fundamental outcome;
receiving an indication of limit odds, one of a requested premium and a desired payout, and a selected outcome, for a wager on a selected outcome, the selected outcome corresponding to at least one of a plurality of fundamental outcomes, each fundamental outcome corresponding to a possible outcome of the underlying event;
configuring an equivalent combination of fundamental bets for the wager as a function of the selected outcome of the wager; and determining final odds for the wager by engaging in a demand-based valuation of the fundamental bets in the equivalent combination.

b. the signal encoded with machine-readable information relating to a wager.
81. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to the selected outcome for the wager.
82. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to a requested premium for the wager.
83. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to the event.
84. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to each of the possible outcomes.
85. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to each of the fundamental bets in the betting pool.
86. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to the combination of fundamental bets for each wager.
87. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to an identity of a bettor.
88. The article of manufacture according to claim 80, wherein the information includes information relating to a placement of a wager in the betting pool.
CA002556957A 2003-08-13 2004-08-06 Enhanced parimutuel wagering Abandoned CA2556957A1 (en)

Applications Claiming Priority (3)

Application Number Priority Date Filing Date Title
US10/640,656 2003-08-13
US10/640,656 US7742972B2 (en) 1999-07-21 2003-08-13 Enhanced parimutuel wagering
PCT/US2004/025434 WO2005019986A2 (en) 2003-08-13 2004-08-06 Enhanced parimutuel wagering

Publications (1)

Publication Number Publication Date
CA2556957A1 true CA2556957A1 (en) 2005-03-03

Family

ID=34216340

Family Applications (1)

Application Number Title Priority Date Filing Date
CA002556957A Abandoned CA2556957A1 (en) 2003-08-13 2004-08-06 Enhanced parimutuel wagering

Country Status (8)

Country Link
US (3) US7742972B2 (en)
EP (1) EP1660973A4 (en)
JP (1) JP2007502463A (en)
KR (1) KR20060042266A (en)
AU (1) AU2004267725A1 (en)
CA (1) CA2556957A1 (en)
NZ (1) NZ545886A (en)
WO (1) WO2005019986A2 (en)

Families Citing this family (390)

* Cited by examiner, † Cited by third party
Publication number Priority date Publication date Assignee Title
US6505174B1 (en) 1996-03-25 2003-01-07 Hsx, Inc. Computer-implemented securities trading system with a virtual specialist function
US10586282B2 (en) 1996-03-25 2020-03-10 Cfph, Llc System and method for trading based on tournament-style events
US7268700B1 (en) 1998-01-27 2007-09-11 Hoffberg Steven M Mobile communication device
US7099839B2 (en) * 1999-09-08 2006-08-29 Primex Holdings, Llc Opening price process for trading system
US7206762B2 (en) * 2000-03-28 2007-04-17 Regent Markets Group Ltd. Betting system and method
US7580872B2 (en) * 2000-10-06 2009-08-25 Lic Development Llc Liquid insurance contracts
US10496938B2 (en) 2000-12-20 2019-12-03 Acoustic, L.P. Generating product decisions
US20100010870A1 (en) * 2000-12-20 2010-01-14 Karl Millar System and Method for Tuning Demand Coefficients
US7523047B1 (en) 2000-12-20 2009-04-21 Demandtec, Inc. Price optimization system
US9165270B2 (en) * 2000-12-20 2015-10-20 International Business Machines Corporation Predicting likelihood of customer attrition and retention measures
US7657470B1 (en) 2000-12-20 2010-02-02 Demandtec, Inc. Financial model engine
US10204349B2 (en) 2000-12-20 2019-02-12 International Business Machines Corporation Analyzing customer segments
US7877286B1 (en) 2000-12-20 2011-01-25 Demandtec, Inc. Subset optimization system
US9773250B2 (en) * 2000-12-20 2017-09-26 International Business Machines Corporation Product role analysis
US7302410B1 (en) * 2000-12-22 2007-11-27 Demandtec, Inc. Econometric optimization engine
US7899691B1 (en) 2000-12-20 2011-03-01 Demandtec, Inc. Econometric engine
US7617119B1 (en) 2000-12-20 2009-11-10 Demandtec, Inc. Price optimization with rule relaxation
US7660734B1 (en) 2000-12-20 2010-02-09 Demandtec, Inc. System for creating optimized promotion event calendar
US9785953B2 (en) * 2000-12-20 2017-10-10 International Business Machines Corporation System and method for generating demand groups
US8010404B1 (en) 2000-12-22 2011-08-30 Demandtec, Inc. Systems and methods for price and promotion response analysis
US7311606B2 (en) 2001-02-20 2007-12-25 Cantor Index, Llc System and method for betting on a subset of participants in an event wherein betting parameters may change over time
US20040198483A1 (en) * 2003-04-03 2004-10-07 Amaitis Lee M. System and method for betting on a subset of participants in an event
US20040210541A1 (en) * 2001-05-04 2004-10-21 Jeremy Epstien User interface for a rules engine and methods therefor
US7409367B2 (en) 2001-05-04 2008-08-05 Delta Rangers Inc. Derivative securities and system for trading same
US6862579B2 (en) * 2001-07-10 2005-03-01 The Boeing Company Systems, methods and computer program products for performing a generalized contingent claim valuation
US7366693B2 (en) * 2001-10-31 2008-04-29 Accenture Global Services Gmbh Dynamic credit management
US7386519B1 (en) * 2001-11-30 2008-06-10 Demandtec, Inc. Intelligent clustering system
US7809581B1 (en) 2001-11-30 2010-10-05 Demandtec, Inc. Rule relaxation and subset optimization system
US20060020526A1 (en) * 2002-02-28 2006-01-26 Victor Viner Investment portfolio analysis system
US7747502B2 (en) 2002-06-03 2010-06-29 Research Affiliates, Llc Using accounting data based indexing to create a portfolio of assets
US8005740B2 (en) 2002-06-03 2011-08-23 Research Affiliates, Llc Using accounting data based indexing to create a portfolio of financial objects
US7610229B1 (en) 2002-05-30 2009-10-27 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. System and method for interactively simulating a credit-worthiness score
US7593891B2 (en) 2003-05-30 2009-09-22 Experian Scorex Llc Credit score simulation
US9569797B1 (en) 2002-05-30 2017-02-14 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Systems and methods of presenting simulated credit score information
US9400589B1 (en) 2002-05-30 2016-07-26 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Circular rotational interface for display of consumer credit information
US20040029627A1 (en) * 2002-08-12 2004-02-12 Michael Hannan Skill based lottery system
TW200411503A (en) * 2002-12-31 2004-07-01 Hon Hai Prec Ind Co Ltd A overseas procurement managing system and method
US9818136B1 (en) 2003-02-05 2017-11-14 Steven M. Hoffberg System and method for determining contingent relevance
US20040193469A1 (en) * 2003-03-31 2004-09-30 Cantor Index Llc System and method for spread betting on a participant in a group of events
US8353763B2 (en) 2003-03-31 2013-01-15 Cantor Index, Llc System and method for betting on a participant in a group of events
US7233922B2 (en) * 2003-04-02 2007-06-19 Cantor Index Llc System and method for wagering-based transferable financial instruments
US7962400B2 (en) 2003-04-02 2011-06-14 Cfph, Llc System and method for wagering based on the movement of financial markets
US20060135252A1 (en) * 2004-12-22 2006-06-22 Amaitis Lee M System and method for betting on a subset of participants in an event according to multiple groups
US7641549B2 (en) 2003-04-11 2010-01-05 Cantor Index Llc Lottery and auction based tournament entry exchange platform
US7676421B2 (en) 2003-04-24 2010-03-09 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for providing an automated auction for internalization and complex orders in a hybrid trading system
US8346653B2 (en) 2003-04-24 2013-01-01 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Automated trading system for routing and matching orders
US7613650B2 (en) 2003-04-24 2009-11-03 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Hybrid trading system for concurrently trading securities or derivatives through both electronic and open-outcry trading mechanisms
US7552083B2 (en) * 2003-04-24 2009-06-23 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Hybrid trading system for concurrently trading through both electronic and open-outcry trading mechanisms
US7653588B2 (en) 2003-04-24 2010-01-26 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for providing order routing to a virtual crowd in a hybrid trading system
US7996297B2 (en) 2003-05-15 2011-08-09 Cantor Index, Llc System and method for providing access to and managing account activity for an online account
US7925577B2 (en) * 2003-05-15 2011-04-12 Cantor Index Llc System and method for establishing and providing access to various types of online accounts
US8799121B2 (en) * 2003-05-15 2014-08-05 Cantor Index, Llc System and method for managing trading order requests
US8001039B2 (en) * 2003-05-15 2011-08-16 Cantor Index, Llc System and method for establishing and providing access to an online account
US7835974B2 (en) * 2003-05-15 2010-11-16 Cantor Index, LLC. System and method for managing risk associated with product transactions
US7716113B2 (en) * 2003-05-15 2010-05-11 Cantor Index, Llc System and method for providing an intermediary for a transaction
US7627495B2 (en) * 2003-06-03 2009-12-01 The Boeing Company Systems, methods and computer program products for modeling demand, supply and associated profitability of a good
US7627494B2 (en) * 2003-06-03 2009-12-01 The Boeing Company Systems, methods and computer program products for modeling a monetary measure for a good based upon technology maturity levels
US7314408B2 (en) 2003-07-23 2008-01-01 Igt Methods and apparatus for a competitive bonus game with variable odds
US7890412B2 (en) * 2003-11-04 2011-02-15 New York Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Distributed trading bus architecture
US8292729B2 (en) 2003-12-02 2012-10-23 United Tote Company Methods and systems for presenting pari-mutuel betting options and constructing wagers
US7922585B2 (en) * 2003-12-08 2011-04-12 United Tote Company Methods and systems for communicating parimutuel wager details and results
US20050124408A1 (en) * 2003-12-08 2005-06-09 Vlazny Kenneth A. Systems and methods for accessing, manipulating and using funds associated with pari-mutuel wagering
US8128485B2 (en) * 2003-12-08 2012-03-06 United Tote Company Systems and methods for accessing, manipulating and using funds associated with lottery-type games
US7567931B2 (en) 2004-01-16 2009-07-28 Bgc Partners, Inc. System and method for forming a financial instrument indexed to entertainment revenue
US7698198B2 (en) 2004-01-16 2010-04-13 Bgc Partners, Inc. System and method for purchasing a financial instrument indexed to entertainment revenue
US8738499B2 (en) * 2004-01-22 2014-05-27 Nyse Mkt Llc Binary options on an organized exchange and the systems and methods for trading the same
US8636571B2 (en) * 2004-02-03 2014-01-28 Cantor Index, Llc System and method for managing select five horseracing bets
US9098883B2 (en) 2004-02-03 2015-08-04 Cantor Index, Llc Managing bets that select events and participants
US20050187000A1 (en) * 2004-02-23 2005-08-25 Cantor Index Llc Method for wagering
US7534169B2 (en) 2005-07-08 2009-05-19 Cfph, Llc System and method for wireless gaming system with user profiles
US7637810B2 (en) 2005-08-09 2009-12-29 Cfph, Llc System and method for wireless gaming system with alerts
US20070060358A1 (en) 2005-08-10 2007-03-15 Amaitis Lee M System and method for wireless gaming with location determination
US8092303B2 (en) 2004-02-25 2012-01-10 Cfph, Llc System and method for convenience gaming
US8616967B2 (en) 2004-02-25 2013-12-31 Cfph, Llc System and method for convenience gaming
US7835961B2 (en) * 2004-03-05 2010-11-16 Cantor Index Llc System and method for wagering in a financial market environment
US20050197938A1 (en) 2004-03-05 2005-09-08 Cantor Index Llc System and method for determining odds for wagering in a financial market environment
US7711628B2 (en) * 2004-03-05 2010-05-04 Cantor Index Llc System and method for offering intraday wagering in a financial market environment
US8128474B2 (en) 2004-03-05 2012-03-06 Cantor Index, Llc Computer graphics processing methods and systems for presentation of graphics objects or text in a wagering environment
US7582013B2 (en) 2004-03-10 2009-09-01 Cfph, L.L.C. System and method for high-speed pari-mutuel wagering using a clearinghouse
US7442124B2 (en) * 2004-03-10 2008-10-28 Bgc Partners, Inc. System and method for high-speed pari-mutuel wagering
US20050245308A1 (en) 2004-04-29 2005-11-03 Cfph, Llc System and method for wagering based on financial market indicators
US7637807B2 (en) 2004-04-29 2009-12-29 Cfph, L.L.C. System and method for mapping results from sporting events to game inputs
US7566270B2 (en) 2004-04-29 2009-07-28 Cfph, Llc System and method for wagering based on multiple financial market indicators
US20090011813A1 (en) * 2004-05-27 2009-01-08 Jack Saffron Lottery system based on sporting events
US7536333B1 (en) * 2004-06-14 2009-05-19 Joseph Hy Omansky System of hedge fund ratings
EP1779272A4 (en) * 2004-08-02 2010-03-31 Schlumberger Holdings Method apparatus and system for visualization of probabilistic models
US7590589B2 (en) 2004-09-10 2009-09-15 Hoffberg Steven M Game theoretic prioritization scheme for mobile ad hoc networks permitting hierarchal deference
US8732004B1 (en) 2004-09-22 2014-05-20 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Automated analysis of data to generate prospect notifications based on trigger events
US7574391B1 (en) 2004-09-30 2009-08-11 Trading Technologies International Inc. System and method for improved order entry using market depth
US8140423B2 (en) * 2004-12-10 2012-03-20 Nyfix, Inc. Controlling an order slicer for trading a financial instrument
US7584134B2 (en) 2004-12-21 2009-09-01 Weather Risk Solutions, Llc Graphical user interface for financial activity concerning tropical weather events
US7584133B2 (en) 2004-12-21 2009-09-01 Weather Risk Solutions Llc Financial activity based on tropical weather events
US7783543B2 (en) 2004-12-21 2010-08-24 Weather Risk Solutions, Llc Financial activity based on natural peril events
US7783542B2 (en) 2004-12-21 2010-08-24 Weather Risk Solutions, Llc Financial activity with graphical user interface based on natural peril events
US7783544B2 (en) 2004-12-21 2010-08-24 Weather Risk Solutions, Llc Financial activity concerning tropical weather events
US8266042B2 (en) * 2004-12-21 2012-09-11 Weather Risk Solutions, Llc Financial activity based on natural peril events
US7693766B2 (en) 2004-12-21 2010-04-06 Weather Risk Solutions Llc Financial activity based on natural events
WO2006076810A1 (en) * 2005-01-21 2006-07-27 Perceptronix Medical Inc. Method And Apparatus For Measuring Cancerous Changes From Reflectance Spectral Measurements Obtained During Endoscopic Imaging
US20060167710A1 (en) * 2005-01-25 2006-07-27 King Martin T Method and system for registering potential acquirers of assets that are not currently on the market
WO2006083709A2 (en) * 2005-02-01 2006-08-10 Goldman Sachs & Co. Systems and methods for improving auction liquidity
US7980947B2 (en) * 2005-02-16 2011-07-19 Igt Flexible determination of progressive awards
CA2642604A1 (en) * 2005-03-08 2006-09-14 Gamelogic Inc. Method and apparatus for playing games
JP5076279B2 (en) * 2005-03-17 2012-11-21 富士通株式会社 IT asset management system, IT asset management method, and IT asset management program
WO2006102441A2 (en) * 2005-03-23 2006-09-28 Gamelogic Inc. Casino related event betting
US7809629B2 (en) 2005-04-07 2010-10-05 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Market participant issue selection system and method
US20060252520A1 (en) * 2005-04-22 2006-11-09 Platis Harry B Pari-mutuel wagering on large entrant pools system and method
US20060258438A1 (en) * 2005-05-13 2006-11-16 Harry Platis Online wagering system and method
US8326716B2 (en) * 2005-05-04 2012-12-04 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for creating and trading derivative investment products based on a statistical property reflecting the variance of an underlying asset
US8027904B2 (en) * 2005-05-04 2011-09-27 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for creating and trading corporate debt security derivative investment instruments
US20060253369A1 (en) * 2005-05-04 2006-11-09 Chicago Board Options Exchange Method of creating and trading derivative investment products based on an average price of an underlying asset during a calculation period
US20080313095A1 (en) * 2005-05-04 2008-12-18 Shalen Catherine T System And Method For Creating And Trading A Digital Derivative Investment Instrument
US20060253368A1 (en) * 2005-05-04 2006-11-09 Chicago Board Options Exchange System and method for creating and trading credit rating derivative investment instruments
US8326715B2 (en) * 2005-05-04 2012-12-04 Chicago Board Operations Exchange, Incorporated Method of creating and trading derivative investment products based on a statistical property reflecting the variance of an underlying asset
US20080082436A1 (en) * 2005-05-04 2008-04-03 Shalen Catherine T System And Method For Creating And Trading A Digital Derivative Investment Instrument
US20060253355A1 (en) * 2005-05-04 2006-11-09 Chicago Board Options Exchange System and method for creating and trading a digital derivative investment instrument
US8489489B2 (en) * 2005-05-05 2013-07-16 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated System and method for trading derivatives in penny increments while disseminating quotes for derivatives in nickel/dime increments
US20060258432A1 (en) * 2005-05-10 2006-11-16 Packer Elliot L System, method, and computer program product for networked pari-mutuel gaming
NZ563474A (en) * 2005-05-18 2009-07-31 Cfph Llc System for providing bets regarding intermediate points in a race event using fractional timing
US20060290061A1 (en) * 2005-06-28 2006-12-28 Ralf Wilhelms Wagering system with possible tie
JP4352028B2 (en) * 2005-06-29 2009-10-28 富士通株式会社 Operation policy evaluation system and operation policy evaluation program
US8070604B2 (en) 2005-08-09 2011-12-06 Cfph, Llc System and method for providing wireless gaming as a service application
US10510214B2 (en) 2005-07-08 2019-12-17 Cfph, Llc System and method for peer-to-peer wireless gaming
US8708789B2 (en) 2005-07-26 2014-04-29 Cantor Index, Llc Conducting a jackpot race event
US7713125B2 (en) * 2005-07-26 2010-05-11 Cantor Index, Llc Jackpot race event
US7788164B2 (en) 2005-09-15 2010-08-31 Microsoft Corporation Truth revealing market equilibrium
US20070067230A1 (en) * 2005-09-20 2007-03-22 Brooks Harris Method and structure for raising funding for a public company and financing the issuance of securities
EP1941474A4 (en) * 2005-09-22 2011-03-30 Iq Company Graphical forecasting interface
CN101287446A (en) * 2005-09-29 2008-10-15 尼克塔治疗公司 Antibiotic formulations, unit doses, kits, and methods
US8874477B2 (en) 2005-10-04 2014-10-28 Steven Mark Hoffberg Multifactorial optimization system and method
GB0521511D0 (en) * 2005-10-21 2005-11-30 Crescent Technology Ltd A generalized trend-following trading strategy
US20080033852A1 (en) * 2005-10-24 2008-02-07 Megdal Myles G Computer-based modeling of spending behaviors of entities
US7925560B2 (en) * 2005-12-07 2011-04-12 Morgan Stanley Systems and methods for valuing a derivative involving a multiplicative index
US20070136373A1 (en) * 2005-12-14 2007-06-14 Piasecki David J Intellectual property portfolio management method and system
US20070198386A1 (en) * 2006-01-30 2007-08-23 O'callahan Dennis M Method and System for Creating and Trading Derivative Investment Instruments Based on an Index of Financial Exchanges
US20070185808A1 (en) * 2006-02-03 2007-08-09 Christopher Richards Systems and methods for providing a personalized exchange market
US8103583B2 (en) * 2006-02-22 2012-01-24 Zvi Mowshowitz Computerized transaction method and system
US20070203827A1 (en) * 2006-02-27 2007-08-30 Sheshunoff Management Services, Lp Method for enhancing revenue and minimizing charge-off loss for financial institutions
US9858579B1 (en) 2006-02-28 2018-01-02 International Business Machines Corporation Plan tuning engine
US9785951B1 (en) 2006-02-28 2017-10-10 International Business Machines Corporation Scalable tuning engine
US20070208728A1 (en) * 2006-03-03 2007-09-06 Microsoft Corporation Predicting demographic attributes based on online behavior
US7711636B2 (en) 2006-03-10 2010-05-04 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Systems and methods for analyzing data
AU2007231601A1 (en) * 2006-03-26 2007-10-04 Advanced E-Financialtechnologies, Inc. (Aeft) Real estate derivative financial products, index design, trading methods, and supporting computer systems
US20070250437A1 (en) * 2006-04-06 2007-10-25 Omx Technology Ab Securities settlement system
US7549576B2 (en) 2006-05-05 2009-06-23 Cfph, L.L.C. Systems and methods for providing access to wireless gaming devices
US7644861B2 (en) 2006-04-18 2010-01-12 Bgc Partners, Inc. Systems and methods for providing access to wireless gaming devices
CN101479756A (en) * 2006-05-01 2009-07-08 725105不列颠哥伦比亚有限公司 Economy games having purchasable and obtainable game pieces
US20070260535A1 (en) * 2006-05-02 2007-11-08 Kontogiannis S C Real estate development financing
US8939359B2 (en) 2006-05-05 2015-01-27 Cfph, Llc Game access device with time varying signal
US20080140585A1 (en) * 2006-06-30 2008-06-12 Ronald Hylton Method for improving performance of constant leverage assets based on approximate payoffs
EP2050062A4 (en) * 2006-07-18 2009-07-22 Pipeline Capital Llc Interest rate swap index
WO2008012594A1 (en) * 2006-07-26 2008-01-31 Partygaming Ia Limited Mobile networked gaming system
US11887175B2 (en) 2006-08-31 2024-01-30 Cpl Assets, Llc Automatically determining a personalized set of programs or products including an interactive graphical user interface
US8799148B2 (en) 2006-08-31 2014-08-05 Rohan K. K. Chandran Systems and methods of ranking a plurality of credit card offers
US7664692B2 (en) * 2006-08-31 2010-02-16 Chicago Board of Options Exchange Method and system for creating and trading derivative investment instruments based on an index of investment management companies
US8266026B2 (en) * 2006-09-29 2012-09-11 Chicago Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Derivative products
US8265965B2 (en) * 2006-09-29 2012-09-11 Chicago Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Derivative products
US8036979B1 (en) 2006-10-05 2011-10-11 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. System and method for generating a finance attribute from tradeline data
US8292741B2 (en) 2006-10-26 2012-10-23 Cfph, Llc Apparatus, processes and articles for facilitating mobile gaming
US9306952B2 (en) 2006-10-26 2016-04-05 Cfph, Llc System and method for wireless gaming with location determination
US9483903B2 (en) 2006-11-07 2016-11-01 Igt Gaming device and method for providing wagering for additional symbol functionality and package betting
US8140425B2 (en) 2006-11-13 2012-03-20 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for generating and trading derivative investment instruments based on a volatility arbitrage benchmark index
US8510567B2 (en) 2006-11-14 2013-08-13 Cfph, Llc Conditional biometric access in a gaming environment
US9411944B2 (en) 2006-11-15 2016-08-09 Cfph, Llc Biometric access sensitivity
US8645709B2 (en) 2006-11-14 2014-02-04 Cfph, Llc Biometric access data encryption
US20080120249A1 (en) * 2006-11-17 2008-05-22 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method of creating and trading derivative investment products based on a statistical property reflecting the volatility of an underlying asset
US20080126165A1 (en) * 2006-11-27 2008-05-29 Siemens Ag Dynamic overlay metrics
US8346584B2 (en) * 2007-01-30 2013-01-01 Wisconsin Alumni Research Foundation Method and apparatus for determining design modification effects on a computerized engineering model
US7949586B2 (en) * 2007-01-30 2011-05-24 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for creating and trading derivative investment instruments based on an index of collateralized options
US8606626B1 (en) 2007-01-31 2013-12-10 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Systems and methods for providing a direct marketing campaign planning environment
US8606666B1 (en) 2007-01-31 2013-12-10 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. System and method for providing an aggregation tool
WO2008100916A1 (en) * 2007-02-12 2008-08-21 Pricelock, Inc. System and method of driving commodity consumers to selective retail locations
US8156022B2 (en) * 2007-02-12 2012-04-10 Pricelock, Inc. Method and system for providing price protection for commodity purchasing through price protection contracts
US20080306858A1 (en) * 2007-02-12 2008-12-11 Pricelock, Inc. System and method for enabling hedging customers to lock forward positions with customer-friendly payment options
US20080313067A1 (en) * 2007-02-12 2008-12-18 Pricelock, Inc. Management and decision making tool for commodity purchases with hedging scenarios
US8019694B2 (en) 2007-02-12 2011-09-13 Pricelock, Inc. System and method for estimating forward retail commodity price within a geographic boundary
WO2008103469A1 (en) * 2007-02-21 2008-08-28 Mordecai David K A System and method for dynamic path- and state-dependent stochastic control allocation
US8319601B2 (en) 2007-03-14 2012-11-27 Cfph, Llc Game account access device
US9183693B2 (en) 2007-03-08 2015-11-10 Cfph, Llc Game access device
US8581721B2 (en) 2007-03-08 2013-11-12 Cfph, Llc Game access device with privileges
US20080228659A1 (en) * 2007-03-16 2008-09-18 Dearden Karey B Methods and vehicles for funding retained obligations
US7853499B2 (en) * 2007-03-29 2010-12-14 Board Of Trade Of The City Of Chicago System and method of allocating an incoming order to standing orders
WO2008124719A1 (en) * 2007-04-09 2008-10-16 Pricelock, Inc. System and method for providing an insurance premium for price protection
US20080306776A1 (en) * 2007-04-09 2008-12-11 Pricelock, Inc. System and method for risk acceptance in the provisioning of price protection products
US7945501B2 (en) * 2007-04-09 2011-05-17 Pricelock, Inc. System and method for constraining depletion amount in a defined time frame
US7742982B2 (en) * 2007-04-12 2010-06-22 Experian Marketing Solutions, Inc. Systems and methods for determining thin-file records and determining thin-file risk levels
WO2008131010A1 (en) 2007-04-16 2008-10-30 Cfph, Llc Box office game
US20080268930A1 (en) * 2007-04-26 2008-10-30 Miller Mark E System and method for generating and displaying a horse racing form for use with a virtual horse race
US20080294540A1 (en) 2007-05-25 2008-11-27 Celka Christopher J System and method for automated detection of never-pay data sets
US20090023493A1 (en) * 2007-07-20 2009-01-22 Tung Wan Cheng Betting-products matched bargain method and system
US9961094B1 (en) 2007-07-25 2018-05-01 Xangati, Inc Symptom detection using behavior probability density, network monitoring of multiple observation value types, and network monitoring using orthogonal profiling dimensions
US8050999B2 (en) * 2007-07-25 2011-11-01 Bank Of America Corporation Lender anonymity securities lending using lender trade criteria
US20090049063A1 (en) * 2007-08-16 2009-02-19 Anthony Lacopo Method for enabling a company to manage the execution of a task
US20090149244A1 (en) * 2007-12-10 2009-06-11 Lutnick Howard W Products and processes for a point exchange
US8165953B2 (en) * 2007-09-04 2012-04-24 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated System and method for creating and trading a derivative investment instrument over a range of index values
US8454423B2 (en) * 2007-09-24 2013-06-04 Cfph, Llc Products and processes for gaming with points
US8262465B2 (en) 2007-09-24 2012-09-11 Cfph, Llc Products and processes for a point exchange
US8506393B2 (en) * 2007-09-24 2013-08-13 Cfph, Llc Products and processes for point gaming derivatives
US9690820B1 (en) 2007-09-27 2017-06-27 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Database system for triggering event notifications based on updates to database records
US8249972B2 (en) 2007-11-09 2012-08-21 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for creating a volatility benchmark index
US8651947B2 (en) 2007-11-09 2014-02-18 Igt Gaming system and method providing a multiple-player bonus redemption game
US20090204534A1 (en) * 2007-11-09 2009-08-13 Tilly Edward T Method and system for providing order routing to a virtual crowd in a hybrid trading system and executing an entire order
US8221204B2 (en) * 2007-11-13 2012-07-17 Multimedia Games, Inc. Method, apparatus, and program product for conducting a game having a simulated stock market feature
US10332332B2 (en) 2007-12-21 2019-06-25 Cfph, Llc System and method for slot machine game associated with financial market indicators
US8460085B2 (en) 2007-12-21 2013-06-11 Cfph, Llc System and method for providing a roulette game based on financial market indicators
US8535140B2 (en) 2007-12-21 2013-09-17 Cfph, Llc System and method for providing a baccarat game based on financial market indicators
US8758108B2 (en) 2007-12-21 2014-06-24 Cfph, Llc System and method for slot machine game associated with market line wagers
US8160952B1 (en) 2008-02-12 2012-04-17 Pricelock, Inc. Method and system for providing price protection related to the purchase of a commodity
US11257330B2 (en) 2008-02-15 2022-02-22 Cfph, Llc System and method for providing a baccarat game based on financial market indicators
US8398474B2 (en) * 2008-02-26 2013-03-19 Patent Investment & Licensing Company Method and apparatus for selectively indicating win probability
US8801518B2 (en) * 2008-02-27 2014-08-12 Steven Lipscomb Tournament-style parimutuel wagering system
US8255302B2 (en) * 2008-02-28 2012-08-28 Morgan Stanley System and methods for modeling a multiplicative index
US7945505B2 (en) 2008-03-12 2011-05-17 Liquidity Development, Llc Methods and systems for trading contracts and operating exchanges
US8277296B2 (en) * 2008-03-13 2012-10-02 Aruze Gaming America, Inc. Horse race gaming machine
US8128471B2 (en) * 2008-03-24 2012-03-06 Universal Entertainment Corporation Gaming system, gaming machine and game control method with compensation processing based on lower limit of odds
WO2009142829A1 (en) * 2008-03-31 2009-11-26 Lic Development Llc Contracts exchange system
US20110077075A1 (en) * 2008-05-21 2011-03-31 Aaron John M Method and system for parimutuel wagering on outcomes
US20090291747A1 (en) * 2008-05-21 2009-11-26 Aaron John M Method and system for parimutuel wagering on outcomes
US20090291730A1 (en) * 2008-05-21 2009-11-26 Aaron John M Method and system for parimutuel wagering on outcomes
TWI366106B (en) * 2008-06-18 2012-06-11 Univ Nat Taiwan Science Tech Method for evaluating the performance of an internal network in an enterprise
US8118666B2 (en) 2008-07-15 2012-02-21 Igt Gaming system, gaming devices, and method for providing an enhanced multiple-player bonus redemption game
US20100023373A1 (en) * 2008-07-23 2010-01-28 International Business Machines Corporation System for enabling both a subjective and an objective evaluation of supplier performance
US8317622B2 (en) * 2008-09-08 2012-11-27 Wms Gaming, Inc. Wagering game establishment data import/export architecture
US8332305B1 (en) * 2008-09-22 2012-12-11 Optionmonster Holdings, Inc. Automatic strategy grouping for a trading system
US8639392B2 (en) 2008-09-29 2014-01-28 Battelle Memorial Institute Electric power grid control using a market-based resource allocation system
US20100088162A1 (en) * 2008-10-03 2010-04-08 International Business Machines Corporation Scoring Supplier Performance
US20100088213A1 (en) * 2008-10-07 2010-04-08 Czupek Andrew P System and method for matching one or more incoming order to a standing order based on multiple order priority
US20100088215A1 (en) * 2008-10-07 2010-04-08 Czupek Andrew P System and method for matching one or more incoming order to a standing order based on multiple order priority allocation
US8566218B2 (en) * 2008-10-07 2013-10-22 Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. Systems and methods for matching one or more incoming order to a standing order as a function of an inner market parameter
US8732062B2 (en) * 2008-10-07 2014-05-20 Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. System and method for matching one or more incoming order to a standing order based on multi-level allocation
US20100088216A1 (en) * 2008-10-07 2010-04-08 Czupek Andrew P System and method for matching one or more incoming order to a standing order based on time order priority allocation
US8788381B2 (en) * 2008-10-08 2014-07-22 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated System and method for creating and trading a digital derivative investment instrument
US20100100474A1 (en) * 2008-10-21 2010-04-22 Van Slyke Oakley E Methods of determining transaction prices on electronic trading exchanges
US20100138361A1 (en) * 2008-10-22 2010-06-03 Mk Asset, Inc. System and method of security pricing for portfolio management system
US9692713B2 (en) 2008-11-12 2017-06-27 Teloip Inc. System, apparatus and method for providing a virtual network edge and overlay
US9929964B2 (en) 2008-11-12 2018-03-27 Teloip Inc. System, apparatus and method for providing aggregation of connections with a secure and trusted virtual network overlay
US9426029B2 (en) 2008-11-12 2016-08-23 Teloip Inc. System, apparatus and method for providing improved performance of aggregated/bonded network connections with cloud provisioning
US8155158B2 (en) * 2008-11-12 2012-04-10 Patricio Humberto Saavedra System, apparatus and method for providing aggregated network connections
US9264350B2 (en) 2008-11-12 2016-02-16 Teloip Inc. System, apparatus and method for providing improved performance of aggregated/bonded network connections with multiprotocol label switching
US9264307B2 (en) 2008-11-12 2016-02-16 Teloip Inc. System, apparatus and method for providing improved performance of aggregated/bonded network connections between remote sites
US8152630B2 (en) 2008-11-13 2012-04-10 Igt Gaming system and method having bonus event and bonus event award in accordance with a current wager and one or more accumulated bonus event points
US8241114B2 (en) * 2008-12-04 2012-08-14 Fontaine Anthony L Method and system for placing a wager on a pari-multuel event
US8277311B2 (en) * 2008-12-13 2012-10-02 Harry Platis Wagering web service system and method
US8491378B1 (en) 2009-08-19 2013-07-23 Harry Platis Real time parimutuel wagering system and method
US20100174638A1 (en) 2009-01-06 2010-07-08 ConsumerInfo.com Report existence monitoring
WO2010081165A2 (en) * 2009-01-12 2010-07-15 Battelle Memorial Institute Nested, hierarchical resource allocation schema for management and control of an electric power grid
DK200900162A (en) * 2009-02-03 2010-08-04 Lanng Soeren A new type of technical indicators called probability indicators
US9020857B2 (en) * 2009-02-11 2015-04-28 Johnathan C. Mun Integrated risk management process
EP2398196A4 (en) * 2009-02-16 2015-07-22 Nec Corp Event distribution system, rendezvous node, broker node, load distribution method for event distribution system, method for distribution of load on rendezvous node, distribution route construction method for broker node, storage medium on which load distribution program is stored, and storage medium on which distribution route construction program is stored
US20140297495A1 (en) * 2010-03-18 2014-10-02 Pankaj B. Dalal Multidimensional risk analysis
JP4951648B2 (en) * 2009-04-30 2012-06-13 株式会社コナミデジタルエンタテインメント Charge payment system using virtual currency
JP4955729B2 (en) 2009-04-30 2012-06-20 株式会社コナミデジタルエンタテインメント Charge payment system using virtual currency
US20100280937A1 (en) * 2009-05-01 2010-11-04 Hiatt Jr John C Method and system for creating and trading mortgage-backed security products
US10992555B2 (en) 2009-05-29 2021-04-27 Virtual Instruments Worldwide, Inc. Recording, replay, and sharing of live network monitoring views
US7716087B1 (en) 2009-06-04 2010-05-11 Yung Yeung Methods and system of conducting business-to-business operations by registered sellers and buyers using an internet accessible platform
US7657464B1 (en) * 2009-06-04 2010-02-02 Yung Yeung System and methods of conducting business-to-business operations by registered sellers and buyers using an internet accessible platform
US20100312687A1 (en) * 2009-06-04 2010-12-09 Hybrid Kinetic Motors Corporation Method and System for Facilitating International Investment with Respect to Immigration
US20110065494A1 (en) * 2009-09-11 2011-03-17 Nicholas Kennedy Sports wagering exchange and method therefor
US8321322B2 (en) * 2009-09-28 2012-11-27 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated Method and system for creating a spot price tracker index
US8595120B1 (en) * 2009-10-01 2013-11-26 BATS Global Markets, Inc. Market on close system, method and program product
US20110098105A1 (en) * 2009-10-26 2011-04-28 Ryan William J Supplemental wager methods and apparatus
US8417606B2 (en) * 2009-11-30 2013-04-09 The Bondfactor Company Llc Method, software program, and system for structuring risk in a financial transaction
US9251539B2 (en) * 2010-01-15 2016-02-02 Apollo Enterprise Solutions, Ltd. System and method for resolving transactions employing goal seeking attributes
US20110177862A1 (en) * 2010-01-15 2011-07-21 Lee Amaitis Electrical computers and digital processing systems involving interprogram or interprocess communication regarding amusement devices and games
US8417615B2 (en) 2010-01-19 2013-04-09 Ronald L. Johannes Methods and systems for computing trading strategies for use in portfolio management and computing associated probability distributions for use in option pricing
US9652802B1 (en) 2010-03-24 2017-05-16 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Indirect monitoring and reporting of a user's credit data
US20110281620A1 (en) * 2010-05-13 2011-11-17 Rovi Technologies Corporation Systems and methods for presenting a wagering opportunity related to an athletic competition being broadcast to a user
US8738524B2 (en) * 2010-06-24 2014-05-27 Chicago Board Options Exchange, Incorporated System and method for creating parity on close orders
US8972106B2 (en) 2010-07-29 2015-03-03 Ford Global Technologies, Llc Systems and methods for scheduling driver interface tasks based on driver workload
CN103003854B (en) 2010-07-29 2015-05-27 福特全球技术公司 Systems and methods for scheduling driver interface tasks based on driver workload
US9213522B2 (en) 2010-07-29 2015-12-15 Ford Global Technologies, Llc Systems and methods for scheduling driver interface tasks based on driver workload
US8956231B2 (en) 2010-08-13 2015-02-17 Cfph, Llc Multi-process communication regarding gaming information
US8974302B2 (en) 2010-08-13 2015-03-10 Cfph, Llc Multi-process communication regarding gaming information
US20120058813A1 (en) * 2010-09-08 2012-03-08 Lee Amaitis Systems and methods for interprocess communication of wagering opportunities and/or wager requests
US8356022B2 (en) * 2010-09-10 2013-01-15 Sap Ag Approximate representation and processing of arbitrary correlation structures for correlation handling in databases
US10805331B2 (en) 2010-09-24 2020-10-13 BitSight Technologies, Inc. Information technology security assessment system
JP2012088844A (en) * 2010-10-18 2012-05-10 Landitude Llc System and method for pooling various kinds of stakes
US8930262B1 (en) 2010-11-02 2015-01-06 Experian Technology Ltd. Systems and methods of assisted strategy design
US8583470B1 (en) * 2010-11-02 2013-11-12 Mindjet Llc Participant utility extraction for prediction market based on region of difference between probability functions
KR101272477B1 (en) * 2010-11-05 2013-06-14 롱기튜드 엘엘씨 System and method for pooling wagers of varying type
US8984021B2 (en) * 2010-12-30 2015-03-17 Fti Consulting, Inc. System and method for harvesting electronically stored content by custodian
US20120259792A1 (en) * 2011-04-06 2012-10-11 International Business Machines Corporation Automatic detection of different types of changes in a business process
US8407128B2 (en) * 2011-04-08 2013-03-26 Atlas Risk Advisory Ltd Systems and methods for foreign exchange risk management
US9589297B2 (en) 2011-04-28 2017-03-07 Battelle Memorial Institute Preventing conflicts among bid curves used with transactive controllers in a market-based resource allocation system
US9245297B2 (en) 2011-04-28 2016-01-26 Battelle Memorial Institute Forward-looking transactive pricing schemes for use in a market-based resource allocation system
US9558519B1 (en) 2011-04-29 2017-01-31 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Exposing reporting cycle information
US9697695B2 (en) 2011-06-15 2017-07-04 Longitude Llc Enhanced parimutuel wagering filter
WO2012174333A1 (en) * 2011-06-15 2012-12-20 Longitude Llc Enhanced parimutuel wagering
JP5189670B2 (en) * 2011-06-30 2013-04-24 楽天株式会社 Lottery purchase system, lottery purchase system control method, program, and recording medium
US20130024344A1 (en) * 2011-07-19 2013-01-24 Chicago Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Bifurcated commodity identifiers
AU2012298732A1 (en) 2011-08-23 2014-02-27 Research Affiliates, Llc Using accounting data based indexing to create a portfolio of financial objects
US8532798B2 (en) 2011-08-23 2013-09-10 Longitude Llc Predicting outcomes of future sports events based on user-selected inputs
US20130060673A1 (en) * 2011-09-02 2013-03-07 Pavan Shah Margin Requirement Determination for Variance Derivatives
US9257000B2 (en) * 2011-09-26 2016-02-09 Lou Tavano Method and system for varying the take-out or rake rate on wagers placed in a wagering pool
US10121322B2 (en) 2011-09-26 2018-11-06 Takeoutrate.Com, Llc Method and system for varying the take-out or rake rate on wagers placed in a wagering pool
US8430748B2 (en) 2011-09-26 2013-04-30 Lou Tavano Method and system for varying take-out on pari-mutuel wagers
US8662980B2 (en) 2011-09-28 2014-03-04 Igt Gaming system, gaming device, and method for providing a multiple player persistent game
US8475265B2 (en) 2011-09-28 2013-07-02 Igt Gaming system, gaming device, and method for providing a multiple player persistent game
US8905831B2 (en) 2011-09-28 2014-12-09 Igt Gaming system, gaming device, and method for providing a multiple player persistent game
JP5812803B2 (en) * 2011-10-28 2015-11-17 渡辺 正樹 Voting system in public competition
US11030562B1 (en) 2011-10-31 2021-06-08 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Pre-data breach monitoring
US11068979B1 (en) * 2011-11-07 2021-07-20 Nyse Chicago, Inc. Fee/rebate contingent order matching system and method
US8814656B2 (en) 2011-12-12 2014-08-26 Igt Gaming system, gaming device, and method providing one or more wild reel wager options
WO2013096963A1 (en) 2011-12-23 2013-06-27 Razor Sports Inc. Progressive betting pools
AU2012327165B2 (en) 2012-01-23 2015-07-16 Accenture Global Services Limited Unified wagering data model
WO2013116359A1 (en) 2012-01-30 2013-08-08 Cfph, Llc Event wagering with group and/or in run options
US8676661B2 (en) 2012-02-17 2014-03-18 Artases OIKONOMIDIS Commodity backed payment system for social networks
US9076304B1 (en) * 2012-02-27 2015-07-07 Dan Setzman Method and apparatus to implement a wager on a randomly picked winning team
US8676866B2 (en) 2012-03-19 2014-03-18 Sap Ag Computing canonical hierarchical schemas
US8795063B2 (en) 2012-03-27 2014-08-05 Igt Gaming system, gaming device, and method for providing a multiple player game
US8473474B1 (en) * 2012-03-28 2013-06-25 Sap Ag Granularity-adaptive extraction of correlation structures in databases
US20130262624A1 (en) * 2012-04-03 2013-10-03 Agustin ACEBO RUIZ Method and System for the Dissemination of the Profiles That a User Has on the Various Online Social Networks
US10643281B2 (en) * 2012-04-06 2020-05-05 Refinitiv Us Organization Llc Price target builder
US8868459B2 (en) 2012-06-18 2014-10-21 Exago Ventures, S.A. System and method for adjusting asset value and availability in data records for mitigating speculative trading in a prediction market
US8708804B2 (en) 2012-06-22 2014-04-29 Igt Gaming system and method providing a collection game including at least one customizable award collector
US9159056B2 (en) 2012-07-10 2015-10-13 Spigit, Inc. System and method for determining the value of a crowd network
WO2014058520A2 (en) * 2012-08-01 2014-04-17 Anthony Scott Oddo Gaming system and method
US20140106836A1 (en) * 2012-10-12 2014-04-17 Nous Global Limited Games for evaluating financial forecasting skill
USD759698S1 (en) 2012-10-12 2016-06-21 Optionsxpress Holdings, Inc. Display screen or portion thereof with a graphical user interface
US10255598B1 (en) 2012-12-06 2019-04-09 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Credit card account data extraction
CA2837414C (en) 2012-12-14 2022-12-13 Battelle Memorial Institute Transactive control and coordination framework and associated toolkit functions
CA2838453C (en) 2012-12-31 2022-08-30 Battelle Memorial Institute Distributed hierarchical control architecture for integrating smart grid assets during normal and disrupted operations
US9824542B2 (en) * 2013-02-06 2017-11-21 Cfph, Llc Aggregate gaming funds
US9881337B2 (en) 2013-02-22 2018-01-30 Cantor Futures Exchange, L.P. Systems and methods for providing seamless transitions between graphical images on a binary options interface
US9870589B1 (en) 2013-03-14 2018-01-16 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Credit utilization tracking and reporting
US9208647B2 (en) * 2013-03-15 2015-12-08 Ballcraps Llc Scalable automated real-time management of peer-to-peer wagers based on events occurring during external contexts
CA2846787A1 (en) * 2013-03-18 2014-09-18 Richard A. Herbert Pari-mutuel bonus round for historical racing device
US20150006349A1 (en) * 2013-06-28 2015-01-01 D. E. Shaw & Co., L.P. Electronic Trading Auction With Orders Interpreted Using Future Information
US20150006350A1 (en) * 2013-06-28 2015-01-01 D.E. Shaw & Co., L.P. Electronic Trading Auction with Randomized Acceptance Phase and Order Execution
US10545938B2 (en) 2013-09-30 2020-01-28 Spigit, Inc. Scoring members of a set dependent on eliciting preference data amongst subsets selected according to a height-balanced tree
US9824397B1 (en) 2013-10-23 2017-11-21 Allstate Insurance Company Creating a scene for property claims adjustment
US10269074B1 (en) 2013-10-23 2019-04-23 Allstate Insurance Company Communication schemes for property claims adjustments
US10262362B1 (en) 2014-02-14 2019-04-16 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Automatic generation of code for attributes
US10282704B2 (en) * 2014-03-07 2019-05-07 Jerry L. Mills System and method for controlling sale of a company
US10475123B2 (en) * 2014-03-17 2019-11-12 Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. Coupon blending of swap portfolio
US9911283B2 (en) * 2014-03-20 2018-03-06 Gamblit Gaming, Llc Pari-mutuel-based skill wagering interleaved game
US11055967B2 (en) 2014-03-26 2021-07-06 Cfph, Llc Event wagering with group and/or in run options
US10009237B1 (en) 2014-08-24 2018-06-26 Virtual Instruments Worldwide Cross silo time stiching
US10250470B1 (en) 2014-08-24 2019-04-02 Virtual Instruments Worldwide Push pull data collection
AU2014406560A1 (en) 2014-09-17 2017-05-04 Teloip Inc. System, apparatus and method for providing improved performance of aggregated/bonded network connections with multiprotocol label switching
US10607303B2 (en) 2014-09-26 2020-03-31 Battelle Memorial Institute Coordination of thermostatically controlled loads
US10127609B2 (en) * 2014-09-30 2018-11-13 The Debt Exchange, Inc. Computer runtime optimization for system supporting asset-level bids on a portfolio with maximum and minimum constraints
US9947174B2 (en) 2014-10-30 2018-04-17 Microsoft Technology Licensing, Llc Computer system for multiple user, multiple event real-time online wagering
US10445152B1 (en) 2014-12-19 2019-10-15 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Systems and methods for dynamic report generation based on automatic modeling of complex data structures
KR101561440B1 (en) * 2015-03-17 2015-10-20 강인준 How to create a winning number expected range
CA2977147C (en) * 2015-04-08 2023-05-23 Equilottery Llc Method and system for wagering on sporting events
US20160358256A1 (en) * 2015-06-02 2016-12-08 Noah P. Healy System and method of price discovery for exchange market
US9935858B1 (en) 2015-08-24 2018-04-03 Xangati, Inc Enhanched flow processing
US20170061501A1 (en) * 2015-09-01 2017-03-02 King.Com Limited Method and system for predicting data warehouse capacity using sample data
US11288739B2 (en) 2015-10-12 2022-03-29 Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. Central limit order book automatic triangulation system
US11164248B2 (en) 2015-10-12 2021-11-02 Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. Multi-modal trade execution with smart order routing
US11410230B1 (en) 2015-11-17 2022-08-09 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Realtime access and control of secure regulated data
US10757154B1 (en) 2015-11-24 2020-08-25 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Real-time event-based notification system
WO2017135614A1 (en) * 2016-02-06 2017-08-10 주식회사 에스브이 Method and system for product sales promotion using sales profit distribution
EP3862958A1 (en) * 2016-02-23 2021-08-11 Nchain Holdings Limited Methods and systems for the efficient transfer of entities on a blockchain
US11061876B2 (en) * 2016-11-15 2021-07-13 Sap Se Fast aggregation on compressed data
CA3050139A1 (en) 2017-01-31 2018-08-09 Experian Information Solutions, Inc. Massive scale heterogeneous data ingestion and user resolution
US20180293656A1 (en) * 2017-04-06 2018-10-11 Brass Ring International Density Enterprise Limited Algorithmic system for dynamic conditional asset pricing analysis and financial intelligence technology platform automation
US11159044B2 (en) 2017-07-14 2021-10-26 Battelle Memorial Institute Hierarchal framework for integrating distributed energy resources into distribution systems
CN109685964B (en) * 2017-10-19 2021-06-29 阿里巴巴集团控股有限公司 Data processing method and interface processing method and device for lottery application program
US20200184551A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2020-06-11 2Bc Innovations, Llc Servicing a plurality of rived longevity-contingent assets
US20200402167A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2020-12-24 2Bc Innovations, Llc Updating a portfolio of blockchain-encoded rived longevity-contingent instruments
US20200349653A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2020-11-05 2Bc Innovations, Llc Servicing a portfolio of blockchain-encoded rived longevity-contingent instruments
US20200265522A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2020-08-20 2Bc Innovations, Llc Riving longevity-contingent instruments
US20210004906A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2021-01-07 2Bc Innovations, Llc Modifying a portfolio of blockchain-encoded rived longevity-contingent instruments
US20200394718A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2020-12-17 2Bc Innovations, Llc Utilizing a portfolio of blockchain-encoded rived longevity-contingent instruments
US20200090280A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2020-03-19 2Bc Innovations, Llc Servicing a plurality of longevity-contingent assets with shared liabilities
US20210099284A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2021-04-01 2Bc Innovations, Llc Modifying blockchain-encoded records of rived longevity-contingent instruments
US20200074556A1 (en) * 2018-02-08 2020-03-05 2Bc Innovations, Llc Servicing a plurality of longevity-contingent assets
US10257219B1 (en) * 2018-03-12 2019-04-09 BitSight Technologies, Inc. Correlated risk in cybersecurity
US10971932B2 (en) 2018-03-21 2021-04-06 Battelle Memorial Institute Control approach for power modulation of end-use loads
US11062392B1 (en) * 2018-03-30 2021-07-13 Wells Fargo Bank, N.A. Systems and methods of personalized inflation modeling based on activity monitoring
US10748385B2 (en) * 2018-03-30 2020-08-18 Inspired Gaming (Uk) Limited Method and apparatus for storing a plurality of wager data from a plurality of individual wagers in a parimutuel wagering system
US10880313B2 (en) 2018-09-05 2020-12-29 Consumerinfo.Com, Inc. Database platform for realtime updating of user data from third party sources
US11361392B2 (en) 2018-11-01 2022-06-14 Battelle Memorial Institute Flexible allocation of energy storage in power grids
US11451061B2 (en) 2018-11-02 2022-09-20 Battelle Memorial Institute Reconfiguration of power grids during abnormal conditions using reclosers and distributed energy resources
US11494839B2 (en) * 2018-11-23 2022-11-08 Nasdaq, Inc. Systems and methods of matching customizable data transaction requests
US11410243B2 (en) * 2019-01-08 2022-08-09 Clover Health Segmented actuarial modeling
US11080160B1 (en) 2019-01-29 2021-08-03 Virtual Instruments Worldwide, Inc. Self-learning and best-practice profiling and alerting with relative and absolute capacity
US10970971B2 (en) 2019-05-06 2021-04-06 Synergy Blue Llc Regulated casino games and gaming machines configured to offer conditional wins and/or conditional win opportunities
US11449936B2 (en) * 2019-06-18 2022-09-20 Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. Distributed credit control with centralized allocation
US11032244B2 (en) 2019-09-30 2021-06-08 BitSight Technologies, Inc. Systems and methods for determining asset importance in security risk management
US11062563B2 (en) * 2019-10-02 2021-07-13 Igt System and method for incentivizing purchases in association with a gaming establishment retail account
CN110796377B (en) * 2019-10-31 2022-03-29 云南电网有限责任公司信息中心 Power grid service system monitoring method supporting fuzzy theory
US11605268B2 (en) 2019-11-22 2023-03-14 Castle Hill Holding Llc System and method for wagering on past events
CN112687046A (en) * 2019-12-13 2021-04-20 北京中体骏彩信息技术有限公司 Method and system for balancing prize winning rate and prize returning rate of prize pool
US11151835B2 (en) * 2020-02-14 2021-10-19 Adrenalineip AI wager odds adjuster
KR102252859B1 (en) * 2020-05-04 2021-05-14 윤성민 Foreign currency exchange system and method thereof
US11948434B2 (en) 2021-02-02 2024-04-02 Castle Hill Holding Llc Method and system for conducting wagers
GB2619647A (en) * 2021-04-10 2023-12-13 Earl Tucker Jeremy System and methods for event outcome selection
US11488442B1 (en) 2021-07-08 2022-11-01 Nasdaq Technology Ab Pari-mutuel pool calculation engine across multiple processors

Family Cites Families (55)

* Cited by examiner, † Cited by third party
Publication number Priority date Publication date Assignee Title
US4903201A (en) * 1983-11-03 1990-02-20 World Energy Exchange Corporation Automated futures trading exchange
US5644727A (en) 1987-04-15 1997-07-01 Proprietary Financial Products, Inc. System for the operation and management of one or more financial accounts through the use of a digital communication and computation system for exchange, investment and borrowing
US4953085A (en) * 1987-04-15 1990-08-28 Proprietary Financial Products, Inc. System for the operation of a financial account
JPS6419496A (en) 1987-07-15 1989-01-23 Omron Tateisi Electronics Co Automatic paying apparatus
JPH067749Y2 (en) 1987-07-24 1994-03-02 有限会社太陽鉄琴研究所 Wheel-running toy with a piano and a metallophone
US5101353A (en) * 1989-05-31 1992-03-31 Lattice Investments, Inc. Automated system for providing liquidity to securities markets
US6336103B1 (en) * 1989-08-02 2002-01-01 Nardin L. Baker Rapid method of analysis for correlation of asset return to future financial liabilities
US5148365A (en) * 1989-08-15 1992-09-15 Dembo Ron S Scenario optimization
US5220500A (en) * 1989-09-19 1993-06-15 Batterymarch Investment System Financial management system
US5608620A (en) * 1990-03-19 1997-03-04 Lundgren; Carl A. Method of eliciting unbiased forecasts by relating a forecaster's pay to the forecaster's contribution to a collective forecast
US5313560A (en) * 1990-05-11 1994-05-17 Hitachi, Ltd. Method for determining a supplemental transaction changing a decided transaction to satisfy a target
US5524187A (en) * 1991-03-25 1996-06-04 The Trustees Of Columbia University Worlds-within-worlds nested display and interaction system and method
US6134536A (en) * 1992-05-29 2000-10-17 Swychco Infrastructure Services Pty Ltd. Methods and apparatus relating to the formulation and trading of risk management contracts
US5970479A (en) * 1992-05-29 1999-10-19 Swychco Infrastructure Services Pty. Ltd. Methods and apparatus relating to the formulation and trading of risk management contracts
US5275400A (en) * 1992-06-11 1994-01-04 Gary Weingardt Pari-mutuel electronic gaming
US5794207A (en) * 1996-09-04 1998-08-11 Walker Asset Management Limited Partnership Method and apparatus for a cryptographically assisted commercial network system designed to facilitate buyer-driven conditional purchase offers
US6456982B1 (en) * 1993-07-01 2002-09-24 Dragana N. Pilipovic Computer system for generating projected data and an application supporting a financial transaction
WO1995022883A2 (en) * 1994-02-24 1995-08-31 Grantley Thomas Aubrey Hall Specified return determinator
US5573244A (en) * 1994-02-28 1996-11-12 International Sports Wagering, Inc. System and method for wagering at fixed handicaps and/or odds on a sports event
US5842921A (en) * 1994-02-28 1998-12-01 International Sports Wagering, Inc. System and method for wagering at fixed handicaps and/or odds on a sports event
EP0686926A3 (en) * 1994-05-24 1996-06-12 Ron S Dembo Method and apparatus for optimal portfolio replication
US6263321B1 (en) * 1994-07-29 2001-07-17 Economic Inventions, Llc Apparatus and process for calculating an option
AUPM811094A0 (en) * 1994-09-13 1994-10-06 Totalizator Agency Board A combined totalizer and fixed odds betting system and method
US5749785A (en) * 1994-09-21 1998-05-12 Rossides; Michael T. Communications system using bets
US5845266A (en) * 1995-12-12 1998-12-01 Optimark Technologies, Inc. Crossing network utilizing satisfaction density profile with price discovery features
US5564701A (en) * 1995-04-28 1996-10-15 Dettor; Michael K. Casino oriented gaming apparatus and method incorporating randomly generated numbers
US5830068A (en) * 1995-09-08 1998-11-03 Ods Technologies, L.P. Interactive wagering systems and processes
US5806048A (en) * 1995-10-12 1998-09-08 Mopex, Inc. Open end mutual fund securitization process
US5819237A (en) * 1996-02-13 1998-10-06 Financial Engineering Associates, Inc. System and method for determination of incremental value at risk for securities trading
US6061662A (en) * 1997-08-15 2000-05-09 Options Technology Company, Inc. Simulation method and system for the valuation of derivative financial instruments
US6247000B1 (en) * 1996-08-21 2001-06-12 Crossmar, Inc. Method and system for confirmation and settlement for financial transactions matching
US6278981B1 (en) * 1997-05-29 2001-08-21 Algorithmics International Corporation Computer-implemented method and apparatus for portfolio compression
US6594643B1 (en) * 1997-11-14 2003-07-15 Charles C. Freeny, Jr. Automatic stock trading system
US5967896A (en) * 1998-04-06 1999-10-19 Walker Asset Management Limited Partnership Method and apparatus for controlling a gaming device having a plurality of balances
US6085175A (en) * 1998-07-02 2000-07-04 Axiom Software Laboratories, Inc. System and method for determining value at risk of a financial portfolio
WO2000008567A1 (en) 1998-08-03 2000-02-17 The Trustees Of Columbia University In The City Of New York Instrumentalities for insuring and hedging against risk
US6418417B1 (en) 1998-10-08 2002-07-09 Strategic Weather Services System, method, and computer program product for valuating weather-based financial instruments
US6317728B1 (en) * 1998-10-13 2001-11-13 Richard L. Kane Securities and commodities trading system
US7020632B1 (en) * 1999-01-11 2006-03-28 Lawrence Kohls Trading system for fixed-value contracts
US6408282B1 (en) * 1999-03-01 2002-06-18 Wit Capital Corp. System and method for conducting securities transactions over a computer network
US6468156B1 (en) * 1999-03-08 2002-10-22 Igt Maximum bonus pay schedule method and apparatus for a gaming machine
US7617144B2 (en) * 1999-03-19 2009-11-10 Primex Holdings Llc Auction market with price improvement mechanism
US6321212B1 (en) * 1999-07-21 2001-11-20 Longitude, Inc. Financial products having a demand-based, adjustable return, and trading exchange therefor
US6418419B1 (en) * 1999-07-23 2002-07-09 5Th Market, Inc. Automated system for conditional order transactions in securities or other items in commerce
JP2001137556A (en) * 1999-11-12 2001-05-22 Akihiro Mino Device and method for sport expecting game, memory medium and transmission medium
US6712701B1 (en) * 2000-03-01 2004-03-30 Ods Technologies, L.P. Electronic book interactive wagering system
AU2001250059B2 (en) 2000-04-05 2006-06-22 Ods Properties, Inc. Systems and methods for placing parimutuel wagers on future events
US20010051540A1 (en) * 2000-04-05 2001-12-13 John Hindman Interactive wagering systems and methods with parimutuel pool features
AUPQ960100A0 (en) 2000-08-24 2000-09-14 Burton, Peter Geoffrey Financial instruments
US6443838B1 (en) * 2000-09-06 2002-09-03 Scott Jaimet Method for defining outcomes of ensembles of games using a single number and without reference to individual game wins
AU2002223957A1 (en) * 2000-09-28 2002-04-08 Hiren Parikh Real-time trading system
JP2002140517A (en) * 2000-11-02 2002-05-17 Kenji Hito Method, device, and system for investment
US7172508B2 (en) * 2001-01-23 2007-02-06 Burton Simon Multi-person parimutuel betting games based on sporting events
AU2003278792A1 (en) * 2002-06-20 2004-01-06 Ka Shun Kevin Fung Method and system for improving the liquidity of transactions
WO2004068286A2 (en) * 2003-01-25 2004-08-12 Mukunya Alfred K System for trading and hedging product and brand sales

Also Published As

Publication number Publication date
KR20060042266A (en) 2006-05-12
EP1660973A4 (en) 2008-04-23
US7742972B2 (en) 2010-06-22
WO2005019986A2 (en) 2005-03-03
JP2007502463A (en) 2007-02-08
NZ545886A (en) 2008-06-30
WO2005019986A3 (en) 2006-06-22
US20040111358A1 (en) 2004-06-10
US8275695B2 (en) 2012-09-25
US8370249B2 (en) 2013-02-05
US20100216545A1 (en) 2010-08-26
EP1660973A2 (en) 2006-05-31
US20110081955A1 (en) 2011-04-07
AU2004267725A1 (en) 2005-03-03

Similar Documents

Publication Publication Date Title
US8577778B2 (en) Derivatives having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
AU2002330092B2 (en) Digital options having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
AU770996B2 (en) Financial products having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
US7389262B1 (en) Financial products having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
US7225153B2 (en) Digital options having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
US8126794B2 (en) Replicated derivatives having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
CA2556957A1 (en) Enhanced parimutuel wagering
AU2002330092A1 (en) Digital options having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
AU2002306697A1 (en) Digital options having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
AU2004201969B2 (en) Financial products having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor
ZA200200359B (en) Financial products having demand-based, adjustable returns, and trading exchange therefor.

Legal Events

Date Code Title Description
FZDE Discontinued